Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Environmental and Natural Resource Economics 3rd ed. Jonathan M

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "Environmental and Natural Resource Economics 3rd ed. Jonathan M"— Presentation transcript:

1 Environmental and Natural Resource Economics 3rd ed. Jonathan M
Environmental and Natural Resource Economics 3rd ed. Jonathan M. Harris and Brian Roach Chapter 5 – Resource Allocation Over Time Copyright © 2013 Jonathan M. Harris

2 Figure 5.1a: Supply, Demand, and Marginal Net Benefit for Copper
Price Supply Ps = Q $150 . e $100 Demand Pd = Q $50 In the current period, equilibrium in the market for copper occurs at P =$100 and Q = This is also known as the static equilibrium. 100 200 Quantity of Copper

3 Figure 5.1b: Marginal Net Benefit for Copper
$150 $100 MNB = Q $50 The marginal net benefit of copper in the current period is obtained by subtracting marginal costs (shown by the supply curve) from marginal benefits (shown by the demand curve). 100 200 Quantity of Copper

4 Figure 5.2: Allocation of Copper over Two Time Periods
Marginal Net Benefit $100 $100 MNB1 MNB2 $75 $75 $50 PV [MNB2] $50 $25 $25 To find the economic optimum allocation between two time periods, the marginal net benefit for the second period is discounted to obtain its present value, and this is compared to marginal net benefit in the first period. This is also known as the dynamic equilibrium. Q1 50 100 150 200 250 Q2 250 200 150 100 50 Quantity of Copper

5 Figure 5.3a: Optimal Intertemporal Resource Allocation
Marginal Net Benefit $100 $100 MNB1 $75 $75 $50 PV [MNB2] $50 A $25 $25 The optimal intertemporal resource allocation occurs where MNB1 = PV[MNB2]. At this point total net benefit is equal to the two shaded areas (A + B). User costs are equal to $25. B Q1 50 100 150 200 250 Q2 250 200 150 100 50 Quantity of Copper

6 Figure 5.3b: Suboptimal Intertemporal Resource Allocation
Marginal Net Benefit $100 $100 MNB1 $75 $75 PV [MNB2] $50 $50 A1 $25 $25 B1 At a suboptimal allocation on Q1 = 200, Q2 = 50, total benefit is A1 + A2 + B1, and the area B2 represents a net loss as compared to the optimum allocation. B2 A2 Q1 50 100 150 200 250 Q2 250 200 150 100 50 Quantity of Copper

7 Figure 5.4a: Market for Copper with User Costs (first period)
Price S’ with User Costs $150 $112.5 Supply $100 Demand $50 If user costs are of $25 are included in the first period, the price rises to $ and the quantity consumed falls from 200 to 150. 50 100 150 200 250 Quantity of Copper

8 Figure 5.4b: Market for Copper (second period)
Price $150 $125 $100 Demand $50 With 100 units remaining in the second period, the price in that period will be $125. 50 100 150 200 250 Quantity of Copper

9 Figure 5.5: Intertemporal Resource Allocation with Different Discount Rates
Marginal Net Benefit PV [MNB2] at: $100 0% MNB1 2% $75 5% 7% $50 10% $25 15% At higher discount rates, the intertemporal allocation of the resource shifts towards the first period, since the present value of the second period marginal net benefit is reduced. 20% 50% Q1 50 100 150 200 250 Q2 250 200 150 100 50 Quantity of Copper

10 Table 5.1: Intertemporal Resource Allocation with Different Discount Rates
Q1 Q2 1 125 2 1.2 132 118 5 1.6 143 107 7.5 150 100 10 2.6 158 92 15 4 170 80 20 6.2 179 71 50 57.7 198 52 As the discount rate rises, the allocation shifts back towards the static equilibrium of 200 units consumption in the first period.

11 Figure 5.6: Hotelling’s Rule on Equilibrium Resource Price
According to Hotelling’s rule, the net price of a resource should rise at a rate equal to the discount rate.


Download ppt "Environmental and Natural Resource Economics 3rd ed. Jonathan M"

Similar presentations


Ads by Google