Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
1
Options Concepts Richard de Neufville
Professor of Engineering Systems and of Civil and Environmental Engineering MIT
2
Theme for Rest of Course
Flexibility Adds Value Enables adaptation to actual future conditions Flexibility Requires a Special Effort Time and Effort to create flexible plans and designs Complexity of design and management Surprisingly, Flexibility often does not cost more: staged development (using smaller increments, deferring additions to system) can reduce both Capital Expenditure (Capex) and Total PV of Development Costs The Central Design issue is: How much Flexibility should we incorporate into system? The analytic question is: How do value flexibility?
3
Outline: Options Presentations - Theory
What is an Option? Learning Objective: Basic concept and use Lattice Model LO: Analysis of time evolution of uncertainty Option Valuation by Lattice (decision analysis) LO: How valuation proceeds through a lattice Dynamic Programming LO: Use of this optimization analysis Arbitrage Pricing of Options LO: Significance and Applicability of Concept Black-Scholes Analysis LO: Use in Financial Markets
4
Outline: Lessons from Options Cases
Merck and Kodak LO: Choice of Decision or ‘Options’ Analysis Antamina LO: Use of Simulation for Valuation Research Development at Ford LO: Hybrid of Decision and ‘Options’ Analysis Complex Engineering Systems LO: Screening Models to Identify Good Options Hydropower Development LO: Path Dependency Issues
5
Objectives of this presentation
To define technical concept of “Options” 4 step ‘Mantra’ To identify types of Options: ‘calls’ and ‘puts’ Build upon their use in financial context To present non-linear asymmetric returns Use of diagrams To indicate drivers of value for options Uncertainty, Time increase value for American options To distinguish range of applications Financial, “ON” and “IN” systems Examples
6
“Options” Embody Idea of Flexibility
An “Option” provides a formal way of defining flexibility An “Option” has a specific technical definition Semantic Caution: The technical meaning of an “option” is… much more specific and limited than … ordinary meaning of “option” in conversation where “option” = “alternative” Pay careful attention to definition that follows!
7
Technical definition of an Option
An Option is... A right, but not an obligation… “Exercise”, that is “use” only if advantageous Asymmetric returns -- “all gain, no pain” Usually acquired at some cost or effort to take some action… to grow or change system, buy or sell something, etc, etc, now, or in the future... May be indefinite But can be for a limited time after which option expires for a pre-determined price (the “strike” price). Cost of action separate from cost of option
8
Illustration of option definition
Spare tire on a car is an “option” because it provides right, but not an obligation… Operator can use it or not Acquired at some cost – price of tire, loss of storage space to take some action… to change the tire now, or in the future... In this case, whenever desired for a pre-determined price (the “strike” price). Time and effort of jacking up car, replacing tire, etc.
9
Types of Options Two basic types of options
CALL: right to take advantage of an opportunity (such as ability to expand garage if demand is high) PUT: right to limit losses of a bad situation (which is what an insurance policy provides) Options in design can be complicated NESTED: one following another (e.g.: successful research provides option on development; successful prototyping provides option on production) SIMULTANEOUS: (e.g.: successful research on fuel cells provides options on hybrid cars and home uses)
10
Financial Options Focus first on financial options because
Consequences easiest to present This is where options and valuation developed Financial Options Are tradable assets (see quotes finance.yahoo.com) Sold through exchanges similar to stock markets Are on all kinds of goods (known as “underlying assets”) Stocks, that is, shares in companies Commodities (oil, meat, cotton, electricity...) Foreign exchange, etc., etc.
11
Types of Financial Options
Two basic types of options Call: right to BUY asset for a set price Put: right to SELL asset for a set price The set price is known as the “strike” price Financial options can get very complicated In addition to Nested and Simultaneous Very exotic possibilities (“Asian”, “Bermudan”, “caput”, etc , etc. -- see en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Exotic_option) Not in this course !
12
Standard Option Terminology
S = fluctuating market price of “underlying asset” S* = S at the moment owner of option takes advantage of right (when option is “exercised”) K = Strike price PAYOFF = owner’s net from a having the option, this is consequence we need to understand Let’s examine what payoff looks like…
13
Call Option Payoff Call Option gives person right to buy an asset for a predetermined “strike” price, K Only rational to exercise right when price of asset is greater than “strike” price: S > K If exercised, option owner pays agreed price of K to get asset worth S* => Payoff = S* - K If unexercised, Payoff = 0 Formally, payoff = Maximum of either 0 or S* K = Max [0, S* K]
14
Payoff Diagram for Call Option
($) S Payoff of Option Price of Asset S - K K Asset Price ($)
15
Example of Current Call Option
Example: A Call Option to buy 100 shares of Google (shares of Google constitute the “underlying asset”) at $350 per share (this is the “strike price”) through Jan. 20, 2006 On Oct. 26, 2005, prices were (finance.yahoo.com) 1 share of Google = $ option to buy 1 share = $ NOTE: option price> immediate value of exercise = $ 3.53 Here’s what the payoff diagram looks like…
16
Payoff Diagram for Call Option
Per share ($) S Payoff of Option Price of Google S - K Current Google Price K= $350 Price of Google share ($)
17
Put Option Payoff Put Option gives person right to sell an asset for a predetermined “strike” price, K Only rational to exercise right when price of asset is LOWER than “strike” price: S < K If exercised, option owner GETS agreed price of K for asset worth S* => Payoff = K - S* If unexercised, Payoff = 0 Net payoff for put = Max [0, K - S*]
18
Payoff Diagram for Put Option
($) Asset Price S K K-S Payoff of Option Asset Price ($) K
19
Example Financial Option
Example: A PUT Option to SELL 100 shares of Google at $350 per share (the “strike” price) Through Jan. 20, 2006 On Oct. 26, 2005, prices were (finance.yahoo.com) 1 share of Google = $ option to sell 1 share = $ NOTE: option value > value of immediate payoff = - $3.55
20
Asymmetry of Option For Call Option, if asset price > strike price… owner then makes profit – that could be unlimited Owner not required to exercise option, so… Loss limited to cost of buying option ( $27.00/share in Google example) Value of option not symmetric For owner of call option: All gain, No pain Note: This applies once you have option. Normally, you have to pay for option, so net value of option (after purchase price, will have possibility of loss Asymmetry is key to option value
21
What drives option value?
How much should you pay to acquire an option? Payoff diagrams show for a given strike price Call payoff increases with asset price increases Put payoff increases with asset price decreases Payoff generally does not reflect full value of option Why is that? Owner exercises only when advantageous In general, owner can wait for a higher price Value is Max[ immediate exercise, waiting]
22
Boundaries on Price Some logical boundaries on value of call option that can be exercised any time (American) Price > 0 Otherwise buy option immediately Price < S Option yields S*- K Option value < S Price > S - K Or buy and exercise immediately Payoff ($) Stock Price ($) K Upper Bound: Call Value Equals Asset Price Lower Bound: S
23
Why Payoff and Value Differ
Consider an option whose current asset price equals strike price: (S = K) (it is “at the money”) Immediate exercise payoff is zero However, if you wait: Payoff might be higher Worst is zero payoff Value of waiting not reflected in immediate exercise, to be added Payoff ($) EV[S] S - K = value of option K Asset Price ($)
24
Value for All Stock Prices
Value exceeds immediate exercise payoff Asymptotically nears immediate payoff for increased S If no upside: value (expectations) = 0 = value (option) Payoff($) S - K Value K Asset Price ($)
25
Option Value Increases with Volatility
Two “at the money” options (S=K) on different assets Both have immediate payoff = 0 Asset A with greater volatility has higher P(larger net payoffs) => higher expected value Asymmetric value favors high variation (limited losses) Payoff ($) Asset A Payoff ($) Asset B pdf S-K S-K pdf K Asset Price ($) K Asset Price ($)
26
Impact of Time Increasing time to expiration increases value of options you can exercise any time (“American”) Ability to wait allows option owner to benefit from asymmetric returns Longer- term contains shorter-term options + more time cannot be worse, can only be better Compare a 3 and 6 month American call Can exercise 6 month call at same time as 3 month Can wait longer with 6 month Which is more valuable? Must be longer one... Time impact not obvious for options with fixed date for exercise (“European”) Could miss out on profitable opportunities
27
Generalized Value of American Call
For a set strike price, value increases with Stock price increases Volatility Time Increased strike price Reduces likelihood of payoffs Reduces call option value Payoff ($) Value increases with volatility and time to expiration S - K Asset Price ($) K
28
Real Options “Real” because they refer to project and systems
Contrast with financial options that are contracts Real Options are focus of interest for Design They provide flexibility for evolution of system Projects often contain option-like flexibilities Rights, not obligations (example: to expand garage) Exercise only if advantageous These flexibilities are “real” options Let’s develop idea by looking at possibilities…
29
Real Options are Everywhere
Examples: Lease equipment with option to buy at end of lease Action is to buy at end of lease (or to walk away) Lease period defined up-front (typically 2-3 years) Purchase price defined in lease contract Flexible manufacturing processes Ability to select mode of operation (e.g. thermal power by burning either gas or oil) Switching between modes is action Continuous opportunity (can switch at any time) Switching often entails some cost (e.g.: set-up time)
30
Generic Real Options Call-like Put-like Compound (nested) In detail…
Capture benefits from increases in project value Exercise typically involves putting money into project Exercise when expectations of positive return increase Put-like Insure against losses from decreased project value Exercise may involve short-term costs or salvage value Exercise when expectations of losses Compound (nested) Projects might contain multiple options Exercise decisions based on overall profit maximization In detail…
31
Call-Like Real Options
Waiting to Invest A project might be profitable today, but better tomorrow Leaving investment opportunity open ~ holding a call Deciding factors: uncertainty resolution; foregone profits Choice based on: Max [immediate investment, waiting, 0] Expand -- Accelerate effort or level of involvement Allows greater participation in upside Cost of expansion is like strike price Choice based on: Max [status quo, expanded project Restart Temporarily Closed Operations Similar to waiting to invest or expand (a special case) Choice based on: Max [remain closed, re-open]
32
Put-Like Real Options Abandon
Ability to halt investment eliminates further losses might include shut-down costs and salvage values Choice based on: Max [continuing, abandoning] Contract -- Decelerate or narrow involvement Reduces participation level and exposure to losses Often incurs short-term scale down costs Choice based on: Max [status quo, contracted] Temporarily Shut Down Operations A special case of contraction Eliminates losses, but can incur shut-down costs Choice on: Max [status quo, temporarily shut-down]
33
Compound or Nested Options
Combinations of Options Many real options exist simultaneously E.g.: those to abandon, contract, or temporarily shut down Complex problem: value of multiple options are often interdependent and in general not additive Exercise may make others valueless (abandon ends project) Switching Between Modes of Operation (example: dual fuel burner case) Flexible systems contain an infinite series of options Allow continual switching between modes of operation If switching modes has a cost, it acts like a strike price For compound options, must value as system
34
Real Options “IN” and “ON” projects
Those “real” because, in contrast to financial options, they concern projects, they are “ON” projects E.g.: the option to open a mine (Antamina case) These do not concern themselves with system design Most common in literature Those “real” because they concern the design elements of system, they are “IN” projects EX: options for staging of system of communication satellites These require detailed understanding of system Most interesting to system designers Financial options Options ON projects Options IN Real Options These need knowledge of system
35
Real Options “ON” projects
These are financial options, but on technical things They treat technology as a “black box” Example: Antamina mine (detailed discussion later) option to open the mine after a two-year exploration period Uncertainty concerns: amount of ore and future price =>uncertainty in revenue and thus in value of mine Option is a Financial Call Option (on Mine as asset) Differs from normal Financial Option because Much longer period -- financial option usually < 2 years Special effort needed to model future value of asset, it can’t be projected simply from past data (as otherwise typical)
36
Real Options “IN” projects
These create options by design of technical system They require understanding of technology Example: Communications Satellites Designers can create options for expansion of capacity by way they configure original satellites Technical skill needed to create and exercise option Differ from other “real” Options because Special effort needed to model feasible flexibility within system itself (e.g.: modeling of ‘trade space” for design of communication satellites)
37
Summary of Introduction to Options
Options embody formal concept of flexibility Options are not “alternatives” 4 step Mantra “right, but not obligation, to act…” “Calls” for opportunities, “puts” for downside risks Options have asymmetric returns => source of value Options are Financial and “Real” Many “real” options available to system designers “Real” Options “ON ” and “IN” systems
38
Appendix Slides Illustrating impracticality of using:
Net present value, discounted cash flows, to analyze flexibility practice decision analysis to analyze complex problems with many possible decision points (stages)
39
Example: Project R&D Risk
Start R&D project for $100,000 (0.1M) $1,100,000 (1.1 M) more to complete development Commercial feasibility determined by initial R&D results Plan to sell (license) technology to highest bidder Revenue estimate 50% chance to sell technology for $2000,000 (2M) 50% chance to sell for $100,000 (0.1M) Assume constant 10% discount rate applies Fund project?
40
Traditional NPV Valuation of R&D
Year 1 2 Initial Cost (0.1) Develop- (1.1) ment License 0.5*2 Revenues 0.5*0.1 Present (0.1) (1) 0.868 Value
41
Tree for NPV Valuation of R&D
Project should be rejected Com Good (1.1/1.1) 0.5 2/1.1^2 Com Bad (1.1/1.1) 0.1/1.1^2 Fund (0.1) Do Not Fund
42
Flexibility Perspective of R&D
Develop only if $2000 license is expected Year 1 2 Initial Cost (0.1) Develop- 0.5*(1.1) ment License 0.5*2 Revenues 0.5*0 Present (0.1) (0.5) 0.826 Value
43
Tree for Flexibility View of R&D
NPV = + 226 Should accept project Commit (1.1/1.1) 2/1.1^2 Abandon Good 0.5 Com (1.1/1.1) 0.1/1.1^2 Bad Fund (0.1) Do Not Fund
44
Lessons from R&D Example
Ability to abandon project has significant value Limits downside Continue only if advantageous Standard NPV misses option value completely Fails to consider effect of intelligent management decisions Standard NPV distorts value when there is risk Assumes that: NPV with expected values = expected NPV “Flaw of the Averages” see article by Savage cited on web However: Consequences of scenarios have asymmetries Example, production costs often not linear with volume Decision analysis has the advantage of recognizing value of flexibility
45
Decision Analysis can be Impractical
Decision Analysis is computationally reasonable for a few stages. However, when we are talking about many stages, and complicated patterns of uncertainties, the analysis may become impractical Case for power plant burners either flexible (gas or oil) compared to Fixed (either gas or oil)
46
Example: Market Risk of Production
Case of Flexible Burner on Power Plant Turbines for electric power generation can be powered by Gas burners Oil burner Flexible, dual use burner (accepts either oil or gas) Fixed technologies (gas or oil) cost less to acquire than more complex flexible burner Under what conditions might flexible systems be valuable?
47
Specifics of Flexible Burner case
Based on Kulatilaka and Marcus paper Price of gas: fixed at $1 per energy unit Price of oil: increases over time In Year 1 oil costs $0.75 per energy unit Price increases 5% per year Discount cash flows at 10% Installation occurs in Year 0 Operations start in Year 1 Revenues are independent of technology What is the NPV for each burner?
48
Oil burner cheaper to operate until Year 6
Base Case: Oil and Gas Prices assumed Known with Certainty Oil burner cheaper to operate until Year 6 Oil and Gas Prices $0.85 $0.95 $1.05 $1.15 $1.25 5 10 Year Price Oil Gas $0.75
49
Cash Flows Under Certainty
50
Results of Certainty Case
Ranking of technologies Oil Flexible Gas Oil burner captures early cost advantages over gas Time value of money means early gains more significant than later losses Oil burner also better than flexible Both capture cost advantages early-on Flexible advantageously switches to gas in Year Extra cost of acquiring flexible > later gains Critical assumption: input prices are predictable
51
What if oil could follow one of three price paths?
More Realistic Case: Uncertainty in Oil Prices What if oil could follow one of three price paths? Oil Prices $1.80 $1.40 High Medium Price $1.00 Low $0.60 $0.20 5 10 Year
52
Cash Flows with Uncertainty
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 O i l P n t R v u . C o s ( H g h ) p = M d i u m ) p = . 4 2 5 7 9 8 3 1 6 C o s t ( L w A v g P V N e a h F l - . 2 9 8 6 5 4 3 N P V F l e x i b a n t R v u 1 7 C o s ( H g h ) p = M d m 0.24 1.00 1 1 . C o s t ( L w ) p = 3 9 4 5 7 2 8 6 A v g P V N e a h F l - 1 . 0.63 .
53
Results of Uncertainty Case
Rank of technologies Flexible -- Oil Gas Flexible technology enabled advantageous switching For high oil price: dual technology better than oil only For high gas price: dual better than gas alone Benefits accrue early on when uncertainty in prices is considered Operating cost savings outweigh additional acquisition costs
54
Lessons from Burner Example
Real Situation can be VERY complicated Prices Change Rapidly They may go up and down in many pathways The switch between fuels can be exercised often Decision Analysis can be Impractical Simple Example Situation Already Difficult Analysis assumed fixed Discount Rate, But Discount rate should reflect volatility of prices As risk changes, so should discount rate Cannot change discount rate in decision analysis Another Method Required!!! => Options Analysis
55
Decision Analysis May be Impractical
Analysis may be too complicated Situation may change too often so that analysis too confused Example: Prices for Basic Resources fluctuate rapidly up and down Inadequate basis for Choosing discount rate When nature of risk constantly changing, … discount rate should also be changing … No single discount rate adequately covers situation See Presentation on Valuation for details
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.