Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Policy Analysis (using examples from Labor Economics) Stepan Jurajda Office #333 (3rd floor) CERGE-EI building (Politickych veznu 7)

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "Policy Analysis (using examples from Labor Economics) Stepan Jurajda Office #333 (3rd floor) CERGE-EI building (Politickych veznu 7)"— Presentation transcript:

1 Policy Analysis (using examples from Labor Economics) Stepan Jurajda Office #333 (3rd floor) CERGE-EI building (Politickych veznu 7) stepan.jurajda@cerge-ei.cz Office Hour: Tuesdays after class

2 Introduction Consider the distribution of wages: What can explain why some people earn more than others? How can we learn from data or models?

3 Overall Distribution of Hourly Wages in the UK - Untrimmed

4 Overall Distribution of Hourly Wages in the UK – trimmed (£1 to £100 per hour)

5 Overall Distribution of CZ Hourly Wages 1Q2006: median: 105CZK, 5 th percentile: 55CZK, 95 th : 253

6 Stylized Facts About the Distribution of Wages There is a lot of dispersion in the distribution of wages Most commonly used measure of wages is hourly wage excluding payroll taxes and income taxes/social security contributions This is neither reward to an hour of work for worker nor costs of an hour of work to an employer so not clear it has economic meaning But it is the way wage information in US CPS, EU LFS is collected.

7 Comments Wage dispersion -- there is also much dispersion in firm-level productivity Distribution of log hourly wages reasonably well-approximated by a normal distribution (the blue line) Can reject normality with large samples More interested in how earnings are influenced by characteristics

8 The Earnings Function Main tool for looking at wage inequality is the earnings function (first used by Mincer) – a regression of log hourly wages on some characteristics: Earnings functions contain information about both absolute and relative wages but we will focus on latter

9 Interpreting Earnings Functions Literature often unclear about what an earnings function meant to be: –A reduced-form? –A labour demand curve (W=MRPL)? –A labour supply curve? (More on models of wage determination later) Much of the time it is not obvious – perhaps best to think of it as an estimate of the expectation of log wages conditional on x

10 An example of an earnings function – UK LFS This earnings function includes the following variables: –Gender –Race –Education –Family characteristics (married, kids) –(potential) experience (=age –age left FT education) –Job tenure –employer characteristics (union, public sector, employer size) –Industry –Region –Occupation (column 1 only)

11 An example of an earnings function – UK LFS all menwomen female-0.175-0.20200 -0.008 00 black-0.04-0.052-0.136-0.032 -0.034-0.056-0.042 indian-0.057-0.072-0.046-0.115 -0.03-0.032-0.043-0.047 pakistan-0.127-0.098-0.086-0.144 -0.052-0.055-0.073-0.084 bengali-0.26-0.178-0.206-0.104 -0.089-0.095-0.116-0.172 chinese-0.093-0.053-0.025-0.033 -0.091-0.097-0.162-0.116

12 Education variables all menwomen degree0.2860.5070.4840.489 -0.011-0.01-0.015-0.012 A' level0.0820.1130.0980.094 -0.009-0.01-0.014-0.013 no quals-0.059-0.105-0.127-0.087 -0.01-0.011-0.017-0.014

13 Family Characteristics all menwomen married + kids0.1110.1210.2010.015 -0.011-0.012-0.018-0.017 married+no kids0.1070.1280.1590.079 -0.011-0.012-0.018-0.016 single+kids-0.02-0.022-0.103-0.045 -0.016-0.017-0.029-0.02

14 Experience/Job Tenure all menwomen experience/100.2310.2640.310.213 -0.011-0.012-0.018-0.016 experience/10 squared-0.046-0.054-0.058-0.051 -0.002 -0.003 tenure/100.1450.1910.1610.225 -0.011-0.012-0.017-0.018 tenure/10 squared-0.02-0.026-0.02-0.036 -0.004 -0.005-0.006

15 Employer Characteristics all menwomen union-0.014-0.043-0.0910.018 -0.008 -0.012-0.011 whether work in public sector0.0310.021-0.0540.063 -0.012-0.013-0.02-0.016 ln employer size0.051 0.070.033 -0.003 -0.005-0.004

16 Industry (selected relative to manufacturing) all men wome n g:wholesale, retail trade-0.158-0.123-0.071-0.142 -0.014-0.013-0.019 h:hotels & restaurants-0.209-0.232-0.21-0.237 -0.022-0.023-0.04-0.028 i:transport & communication0.001-0.016-0.0170.038 -0.014-0.015-0.018-0.027 j:financial intermediation0.1920.2710.3420.217 -0.017-0.018-0.026-0.024 k:real estate, renting0.0480.1070.12 -0.014-0.015-0.02-0.022

17 Region (selected relative to Merseyside) all menwomen inner london0.2770.3090.3120.369 -0.028-0.03-0.047-0.043 outer london0.2220.2490.2530.317 -0.025-0.027-0.042-0.038 rest of south east0.1490.1750.2340.185 -0.022-0.024-0.038-0.035 south west0.0340.030.0690.068 -0.024-0.026-0.04-0.037

18 Occupation (relative to craft workers) – only 1 st column 1 managers and administrators 0.4 6 personal, protective occupations 0.002 -0.015-0.017 2 professional occupations 0.447 7 sales occupations 0.025 -0.017-0.019 3 associate prof & tech occupations 0.263 8 plant and machine operatives -0.04 -0.016-0.015 4 clerical,secretarial occupations 0.041 9 other occupations -0.129 -0.015-0.017

19 Stylized facts to be deduced from this earnings function women earn less than men ethnic minorities earn less than whites education is associated with higher earnings wages are a concave function of experience, first increasing and then decreasing slightly wages are a concave function of job tenure wages are related to family characteristics wages are related to employer characteristics e.g. industry, size union workers tend to earn more (?)

20 The same stylized facts for CZ (1)(2)(1)(2) Female-0.24-0.26Industry relat. to Agriculture Educ. Relat. to PrimaryMining0.260.32 Apprenticeship0.080.07Manufacturing0.21 Secondary w/ GCE0.340.32Utilities0.390.36 College and University0.82 Construction0.220.21 Post-graduate1.04 Retail0.100.08 Age0.04 Hotels0.070.15 Age squared-0.04 Transport0.25 Part-time-0.05 Banks0.540.63 Firm size (employment)0.060.07RealEstate+R&D.-0.02-0.03 Firm size squared-0.020.04Other Services0.120.11 _const3.493.48 Trade unions0.004 N1m0.5m

21 The variables included here are common but can find many others sometimes included Labour market conditions – e.g. unemployment rate, cohort size Other employer characteristics e.g. profitability Computer use- e.g. Krueger, QJE 1993 Pencil use – e.g. diNardo and Pischke, QJE 97 Beauty – Hamermesh and Biddle, AER 94 Height – Persico, Postlewaite, Silverman, JPE 04 Sexual orientation – Arabshebaini et al, Economica 05

22 Raises question of what should be included in an earnings function Depends on question you want to answer E.g. what is effect of education on earnings – should occupation be included or excluded? Note that return to education lower if include occupation Tells us part of return of education is access to better occupations – so perhaps should exclude occupation But tells us about way in which education affects earnings – there is a return within occupations

23 Other things to remember May be interactions between variables e.g. look at separate earnings functions for men and women. Return to experience lower for women but returns to education very similar. R2 is not very high – rarely above 0.5 and often about 0.3. So, there is a lot of unexplained wage variation: unobserved characteristics, true wage dispersion (more on that later when we model the labor market), measurement error.

24 Problems with Interpreting Earnings Functions Earnings functions are regressions so potentially have all usual problems: –endogeneity (correlation between job tenure & wages) –omitted variable (ability) –selection – not everyone works (women with children) Tell us about correlation but we are interested in causal effects and correlation is not causation In this course, well consider empirical identification strategies that get at causality. In economics, we need models to interpret data. Some wage modelling follows.

25 Models of Distribution of Wages Start with perfectly competitive model Assumes labour market is frictionless so a single market wage for a given type of labour – the law of one wage (note: this assumes no non- pecuniary aspects to work so no compensating differentials) law of one wage sustained by arbitrage – if a worker earns CZK100 per hour and an identical worker for a second firm earns CZK90 per hour, the first employer could offer the second worker CZK95 making both of them better-off

26 The Employer Decision (the Demand for Labour) Given exogenous market wage, W, employers choose employment, N to maximize: Where F(N,Z) is revenue function and Z are other factors affecting revenue (possibly including other sorts of labour)

27 This leads to familiar first-order condition: i.e. MRPL=W From the decisions of individual employers one can derive an aggregate labour demand curve:

28 The Worker Decision (the Supply of Labour) Assume the only decision is whether to work or not (the extensive margin) – no decision about hours of work (the intensive margin) Assume a fraction n(W,X) of individuals want to work given market wage W; there are L workers. X is other factors influencing labour supply. The labour supply curve will be given by:

29 Equilibrium Equilibrium is at wage where demand equals supply. This also determines employment. What influences equilibrium wages/employment in this model: –Demand factors, Z –Supply Factors, X How these affect wages and employment depends on elasticity of demand and supply curves

30 What determines wages? Exogenous variables are demand factors, Z, and supply factors, X. Statements like wages are determined by marginal products are a bit loose True that W=MRPL but MRPL is potentially endogenous as depends on level of employment Can use a model to explain both absolute level of wages and relative wages. Go through a simple example:

31 A Simple Two-Skill Model Two types of labour, denoted 0 and 1. Assume revenue function is given by: You should recognise this as a CES production function with CRS

32 Marginal product of labour of type 0 is: Marginal product of labour of type 1 is:

33 As W=MPL we must have: Write this in logs: Where σ=1/(1-ρ) is the elasticity of substitution This gives relationship between relative wages and relative employment

34 A Simple Model of Relative Supply We will use the following form: Where ε is elasticity of supply curve. This might be larger in long- than short-run Combining demand and supply curves we have that: Which shows role of demand and supply factors and elasticities.

35 Data from the US

36 What about unemployment? As defined in labor market statistics (those who want a job but have not got one) does not exist in the frictionless model. Anyone who wants a job at the market wage can get one (so observed unemployment must be voluntary). Failure of this model to have a sensible concept of unemployment is one reason to prefer models with frictions.

37 Before we go there, a reminder Unemployment has different definitions (ILO, registered) US-EU unemployment gap used to be different An unemployment rate does not mean much without an employment rate

38

39

40 The Distribution of Wages in Imperfect Labour Markets Discuss a simple variant of a model of labour market with frictions – the Burdett- Mortensen 1998 IER model. Here, MPL=p with perfect competition but with frictions other factors are important. Frictions are important: people are happy (sad) when they get (lose) a job. This would not be the case in the competitive model.

41 Labour Markets with frictions, cont. Assume that employers set wages before meeting workers (Pissarides assumes that there is bargaining after they meet. Hall & Krueger: 1/3 wage posting 1/3 bargained.) L identical workers, get w (if work) or b. M identical CRS firms, profits= (p-w)n(w). There is a firm distribution of wages F(w). Matching: job offers drawn at random arrive to both unemployed and employed at rate λ; exog. job destruction rate is δ.

42 Labour Markets with frictions, cont. Unemployed use a reservation wage strategy to decide whether to accept the job offer or wait for a better one (r=b). 1. steady state unempl.: Inflow = Outflow: δ(1-u) = λ[1-F(r)]u + 2. In equilibrium F(r)=0 (why offer a wage below r? – youll make 0 profits) => equilibrium u= δ / (δ+λ). Employed workers quit: q(w)= λ[1-F(w)]

43 Labour Markets with frictions, cont. In steady state, a firm recruits and loses the same number of workers: [δ+q(w)]n(w)=R(w)= λL/M[u+(1-u)N(w)] where N(w) is the fraction of employed workers who are paid w or less. Derive n(w): firm employment and profit. Next, get equilibrium wage distribution F(w) & average wage E(w). EQ: all wages offered give the same profit (π=(p-w)n(w) higher w means higher n(w).) + no other w gives higher profit.

44 Average wage is given by: So the important factors are –Productivity, p –Reservation wage, b –Rate of job-finding, λ and rate of job-loss, δ –i.e. a richer menu of possible explanations But, also equilibrium wage dispersion (even when workers are all identical; a failure of the law of one wage) so luck also important (recall the empirical stylized fact of low R2). Perfect competition if λ/δ=. Frictions disappear. Competition for workers drives w to p (MP).

45 Institutions also important Even in a perfectly competitive labour market institutions affect wages/emplmnt Possible factors are: –Trade unions –Minimum wages –Welfare state (affects incentives, inequality) Example: higher unempl. benefit increases the wage share and reduces inequality, but it also increases the unempl. rate thus making the distribution of income more unequal.


Download ppt "Policy Analysis (using examples from Labor Economics) Stepan Jurajda Office #333 (3rd floor) CERGE-EI building (Politickych veznu 7)"

Similar presentations


Ads by Google