Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
1
Vertical Price Restraints
Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
2
Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
Introduction Many contractual arrangements between manufacturers Some restrict rights of retailer Can’t carry alternative brands Expected to provide services or to deliver product in a specific amount of time Some restrict rights of manufacturer Can’t supply other dealers Must buy back unsold goods Some involve restrictions/guidelines on pricing Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
3
Resale Price Maintenance
Resale Price Maintenance is the most important type of vertical price restriction. Under RPM agreement Retailer agrees to sell at manufactured specified price RPM agreements have a long and checkered history In US, Dr. Miles case of 1911established per se illegality for any and all such agreements However, Colgate case of 1919 allowed some “wiggle room” Miller-Tydings (1937) and McGuire (1952) Acts even more supportive in allowing states to enforce RPM contracts Repeal of Miller-Tydings and McGuire Acts reverted legal status back to (mostly) per se illegal State Oil v. Khan decision in 1997 allowed rule of reason in RPM agreements setting maximum price Leegin case applies rule of reason to minimum price Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
4
RPM Agreements & Double Marginalization
Recall the Double Marginalization Problem Downstream Demand is P = A – BQ and Retailer has no cost other than wholesale purchase price Downstream Marginal Revenue = MRD = A – 2BQ MRD =Upstream Demand Upstream Marginal Revenue = MRU = A – 4BQ With Manufacturer’s marginal cost c, profit-maximizing output and upstream price are: and – Downstream price is: Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
5
RPM & Double Marginalization 2
With a vertical chain of a monopoly manufacturer and a monopoly retailer, the downstream price is far too high There is a pricing externality The manufacturer profit is the wholesale price r – cost c times the volume of output Q [= (r – c)Q] Once r is set, manufacturer’s profit rises with Q In setting a markup over the wholesale price, the retailer limits Q and cuts into manufacturer profit But retailer ignores this external effect Retail (and wholesale) price maximizing joint profit < Independent retailer’s price Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
6
RPM & Double Marginalization 3
An RPM restriction that prohibits the retailer from selling at any price higher than P* would permit the manufacturer to achieve the maximum profit There is though an alternative to the RPM, namely a Two-Part Tariff of the type discussed in Chapter 6 Set wholesale price at marginal cost c Retailer will then choose PD = P* = (A + c)/2 and earn profit = (A – c)2/4B Charge franchise fee of T = (A – c)2/4B Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
7
RPM & Price Discrimination
An RPM to prevent double marginalization suggests problem is that the retail price is too high Historical record suggests that perceived problem is often that retail price is too low Need to find reason(s) for RPM agreements aimed at keeping retail prices high Retail Price Discrimination may present case where RPM specifying minimum price can help manufacturer Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
8
RPM & Price Discrimination (cont.)
Suppose retailer operates in two markets One has less elastic demand (monopolized) One has elastic demand (due to potential entrant)—retail price P cannot rise above wholesale price r Manufacturer must use same contract for each Maximum profit in each market = (A – c)2/4B achieved at P* = (A + c)/2 No single price or single two-part tariff can maximize profit from both markets Unless r = (A + c)/2 in elastic demand market, P* cannot be achieved since in that market P = r But there is only one contract, so this implies r = (A + c)/2 in inelastic (monopolized) market and so to double marginalization Solution: write common contract that sets r = c, and imposes RPM minimum price of P=(A+c)/2 Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
9
RPM and Retail Services
So far the retailer has been a totally passive intermediary between manufacturer and consumer Retailers actually provide additional services: marketing, customer assistance, information, repairs. These services increase sales This benefits manufacturers But offering these services is costly, and also both services and costs are hard for manufacturer to measure Retailers interested in her profit not manufacturer’s How does the manufacturer provide incentives for retailer to offer services? Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
10
RPM and Retail Services 2
Think of retail services s and shifting out demand curve similar to the way that quality increases shifted out the demand curve in Chapter 7 $/unit Demand with retail services s = 1 Demand with retail services s = 2 Quantity But cost of providing retail services (s) rises as more services are provided $/unit (s) Service Level s Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
11
RPM and Retail Services 3
As a benchmark, see what happens if manufacturing and retailing are integrated in one firm suppose that consumer demand is Q = 100s(500 - P) Note how s shifts out demand assume that marginal costs are cm for manufacturing and for the cr for retailing the cost of providing retail services is an increasing function of the level of services, f(s) the integrated firm’s profit I is: I = [P-cm-cr-f(s)]100s(500 - P) Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
12
RPM and Retail Services 4
The integrated firm has two choices to make: What price P to charge (what Q to produce); and The level of retail services s to provide To maximize profit, take derivatives of integrated firm’s profit function both with respect to Q and with respect to s and set each equal to zero Cancel the 100s terms pI/P = 100s(500 - P) - 100s(P - cm - cr - f(s)) = 0 P + cm + cr + f(s) = 0 P* = (500 + cm + cr + f(s))/2 Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
13
RPM and Retail Services 5
Cancel the 100(500 - P) terms RPM and Retail Services 5 Now take the derivative with respect to services s and set it equal to pI/s = 100s(500 - P)(P - cm - cr - f(s)) - 100s(500 - P)f’(s) = 0 Solving we obtain: (P - cm - cr - f(s)) = sf’(s) Substituting the price equation into the service equation then yields: (500 - cm - cr)/2 = f(s)/2 + sf’(s) The s that satisfies the above equation gives the efficient (profit-maximizing) level of services Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
14
RPM and Retail Services 6
The left hand side is decreasing in cm and cr RPM and Retail Services 6 The right hand side is increasing in s We can use this equation to show how changes in the production and retailing marginal cost (cm and cr) affect the optimal level of services Suppose now that there is an increase in marginal costs, apart from services, at either the manufacturing or retail level Let cm and cr be initial marginal costs (500 - cm - cr)/2 = f(s)/2 + sf’(s) $/unit The rise in cost leads to a fall in the optimal choice of s from s* to s** f(s)/2 + sf’(s) (500-cm-cr)/2 Let c’m and c’r be new marginal costs (500-c’m-c’r )/2 Service Level s s** s* Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
15
RPM and Retail Services 7
For example let cm = $20, cr = $30 and f(s) = 90s2 Then (500 - cm - cr)/2 = f(s)/2 + sf(s) implies 225 = 45s2 + s180s ; OR 225 = 225s2 s = 1 Then, solving for P we obtain: (P - cm - cr - f(s)) = 180s2 = 180 P= $320 Implying an output level of: Q = 100s(500 - P) = 18,000 The integrated firm earns profit pI = $3.24 million. It chooses the socially efficient level of retail services but sets price above marginal cost. This is our benchmark case. Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
16
RPM and Retail Services 8
Now let manufacturer sell to monopoly dealer If we assume two-part pricing is not possible, then the only way that the manufacturer can earn profit is by charging a wholesale price r above cost cm Cancel the 100s terms – The profit of the retailer is now: pR = (P- r - cr - f(s))100s(500 - P) = (P- r s2 )100s(500 - P) Cancel the 100(500 - P) terms – Retailer sets P and s to maximize retail profit pR/P = 100s(500 - P) - 100s(P - r - 30 – 90s2) = 0 – P = (530 + r + 90s2)/2 pR/s = 100(500 - P)(P - r - 30 – 90s2) - 100s(500 - P)180s = 0 – P – r – 30 = 270s2 Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
17
RPM and Retail Services 9
Put the two profit-maximizing conditions together (500 – r – cr)/2 = (s)/2 + s’(s) OR 225s2 = 235 – r/2 – It is clear that unless r = cm = 20, s will be less than 1, i.e., less than the optimal level of services – Yet absent an alternative pricing arrangement, the manufacturer only earns a positive profit if r > 20. – From the retailer’s perspective, a value of r > 20 is equivalent to a rise in cm and as we saw previously, this reduces the retailer’s optimal service level Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
18
RPM and Retail Services 10
Two contracts that might solve the problem are: A royalty contract written on the retailer’s profit; A two-part tariff Under a profit-royalty contract, the manufacturer sells at cost cm to the retailer but claims a percentage x of the retailer’s profit This works because there is no difference between maximizing total retail profit or maximizing (1 – x) of total retail profit Given that the wholesale cost is cm, the profit-maximizing condition: 235 = 225s2 + r/2 leads to s = 1, the efficient level of services Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
19
RPM and Retail Services 11
Similarly, a two-part tariff could solve the problem: Again, sell at wholesale price cm = $20; As before, this leads to the efficient level of services, namely, s = 1. Now manufacturer can claim downstream profit (or some part of it) by use of an upfront franchise fee However, both royalty and two-part tariff requires that manufacturer know the retailer’s true profit level. This can be difficult if retailer has inside information on the nature of: Retailing cost, cr Retail consumer demand Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
20
RPM and Retail Services 12
Can an RPM solve the problem? It has the advantage that it is easily monitored It also addresses the double-marginalization problem However, it cannot solve the service problem in the present context Without a royalty or up-front franchise fee, manufacturer can only earn profit if r > cm. As we have seen, this in itself leads to a service reduction Imposing a maximum price via an RPM agreement intensifies this fall in service because it reduces the retailer’s margin, P – r, and it is that margin that funds the provision of services Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
21
RPM and Retail Services 13
However, use of an RPM becomes considerably more attractive if retail sector is competitive large number of identical retailers each buys from the manufacturer at r and incurs service costs per unit of f(s) plus marginal costs cr competition in retailing drives retail price to PC = r + cr + f(s) competition also drives retailers to provide the level of services most desired by consumers subject to retailers breaking even so each retailer sets price at marginal cost chooses the service level to maximize consumer surplus Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
22
RPM and Retail Services 14
With competition there is no retail markup and no retail profit P = r + cr + (s) Profit royalty and two-part tariff will not work because there is no profit to share or take up front Given wholesale price r, retailers compete by offering level of services s that maximizes consumer surplus Recall: Demand is: Q = 100s(500 - P) P = r + cr + f(s) Consumer Surplus is therefore: CS = (500 – P)xQ/2 = 50s(500 – P)2 CS = 50s[500 – r – cr – (s)]2 Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
23
RPM and Retail Services 15
By way of a diagram, we have: Triangle = Consumer Surplus. Given r, cr, and (s), competitive retailers will compete by offering services that maximize this triangle $/unit 500 P=r+cr+(s) Q 50s Quantity (000’s) Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
24
RPM and Retail Services 16
Cancel the common term 50(500 - r - cr - f(s)) We can determine the competitive service outcome for any value of r by maximizing CS = 50s[500 – r – cr – (s)]2 with respect to s . This yields CS/s = 50(500-r-cr-f(s))2 -100s(500-r-cr-f(s))f(s) = 0 So: r - cr - f(s) = 2sf(s) (500 - r - cr)/2 = f(s)/2 + sf(s) This equation gives the competitive level of retail services when the manufacturer simply chooses r and lets retailers choose P and s Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
25
RPM and Retail Services 17
Recall: the integrated firm wants to set a price=P* = $320. RPM lets manufacturer impose this price on retailers. With retail price = P* = $320, competitive retailers offer services until they just break even, i.e., until: f(s) = P* – cr – r = 90s2 = 320 – 30 – r By choosing, r = $200, the competitive service level satisfies: 90s2 = 90 s = 1 with P = $320 This is the optimal service level and price. The RPM has led to duplication of the integrated outcome Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
26
RPM and Retail Services 18
Consideration of customer services with competitive retailing also gives another reason that RPM agreements may be useful—the free-riding problem. Many services are informational Features of high-tech equipment Quality, e.g., wine Providing these services are costly But no obligation of consumer to buy from retailer Discount stores can free-ride on retailer’s services Retailers cut back on services Manufacturers and consumers lose out RPM agreements prevent free-riding discounters Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
27
RPM and Variable Demand
RPM agreements may also be helpful in dealing with variable retail demand Retailer facing uncertain demand has to balance how to meet demand if demand is strong how to avoid unwanted inventory if demand is weak monopoly retailer acts differently from competitive monopolist throws away inventory when demand is weak to avoid excessive price fall competitive retailer will sell it because he believes that he is small enough not to affect the price Intense retail competition if demand is weak reduces the profit of the manufacturer makes firms reluctant to hold inventory Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
28
RPM and Variable Demand 2
Suppose that demand is high, DH with probability 1/2 And that demand is low, DL with probability 1/2 Price – Marginal costs are assumed constant at c – Integrated firm has to choose in each period stage 1: how much to produce stage 2: demand known- how much to sell since costs are sunk: maximize revenue DH DL c MC Quantity Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
29
RPM and Variable Demand 3
An integrated firm will not produce more than QUpper Price And will not produce less than QLower the integrated firm will produce Q* DH How is Q* determined MC = MR with low demand MC = MR with high demand DL c MC MRL MRH Quantity QLower Q* QUpper Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
30
RPM and Variable Demand 4
If demand is high the firm sells Q* at price PMax: MR = MR*H If demand is low selling Q* is excessive Price the firm maximizes revenue by selling Q*L at price PMin: MR = 0 Revenue with low demand Expected marginal revenue is: Revenue with high demand MR*H/2 + 0 = MR*H/2 DH Q* is such that expected MR = MC . So, MR*H/2 = c PMax PMin DL Expected profit is MR*H pI = PMaxQ*/2 + PMinQ*L/2 - cQ* MC c MRL MRH Quantity Q*L Q* Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
31
RPM and Variable Demand 5
Suppose that retailing is competitive Will competitive retailers stock the optimal amount Q*? What will happen if they do? Price If demand is high the retail firms sell Q* at price PMax: MR = MR*H Revenue with high demand If demand is low each firm will sell more so long as price is positive DH PMax So, if demand is low competitive retailers keep selling until they sell the total quantity QL at which price is zero DL Revenue is therefore zero in low demand periods if competitive firms stock Q* MC c MRL MRH Quantity QL Q* Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
32
RPM and variable demand 6
If competitive retailers stock Q*, their expected net revenue is thus: PMaxQ*/2 + 0 = PMaxQ*/2 Competitive firms just break even. So, manufacturer can only charge a wholesale price PW such that: PWQ* = PMaxQ*/2 which gives PW = PMax/2 The manufacturer’s profit is then: pM = (PMax/2 - c)Q* This is well below the integrated profit. Competitive retailers sell too much in low demand periods An RPM agreement can fix this. How? Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
33
RPM and Variable Demand 7
Recall: The integrated firm never sells at a price below PMin Price So, set a minimum RPM of PMin In high demand periods Q* is sold at price PMax In low demand periods the RPM agreement ensures that only Q*L is sold DH PMax Expected revenue to the retailers is PMaxQ*/2 + PMinQ*L/2 PMin DL MR*H c MC MRL MRH Quantity Q*L Q* Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
34
RPM and Variable Demand 8
With RPM, expected net revenues of retailers is PMaxQ*/2 + PMinQ*L/2 Manufacturer can now charge wholesale price PW such that: PWQ* = PMaxQ*/2 + PMinQ*L/2 which gives PW = PMax/2 + PMinQ*L/2Q* The manufacturer’s profit is pM = PMaxQ*/2 + PMinQ*L/2 - cQ* This is the same as the integrated profit – The RPM agreement has given the integrated outcome – Consumers can gain too because retailers now stock products with variable demand that would otherwise not be stocked. Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.