Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
1
CHAPTER 4 MONEY and INFLATION
2
In this chapter, you will learn:
The classical theory of inflation causes effects social costs “Classical” – assumes prices are flexible & markets clear Applies to the long run 1
3
U.S. inflation and its trend, 1960-2010
% change in CPI from 12 months earlier In this chapter, we learn about the long-run trend behavior of prices and inflation. source: BLS obtained from The long-run trend line was produced in Excel, type polynomial order 3.
4
U.S. inflation and its trend, 1960-2010
% change in CPI from 12 months earlier long-run trend In this chapter, we learn about the long-run trend behavior of prices and inflation. source: BLS obtained from The long-run trend line was produced in Excel, type polynomial order 3.
5
The connection between money and prices
Inflation rate = the percentage increase in the average level of prices. Price = amount of money required to buy a good. Because prices are defined in terms of money, we need to consider the nature of money, the supply of money, and how it is controlled.
6
Money: Definition Money is the stock of assets that can be readily used to make transactions.
7
Money: Functions medium of exchange we use it to buy stuff
store of value transfers purchasing power from the present to the future unit of account the common unit by which everyone measures prices and values If your students have taken principles of economics, they will probably be familiar with the material on this slide. It might be worthwhile, though, to take an extra moment to be sure that students understand that the definition of store of value (an item that transfers purchasing power from the present to the future) simply means that money retains its value over time, so you need not spend all your money as soon as you receive it. The idea should be familiar, even though Mankiw’s wording is a bit more sophisticated than most other texts.
8
Money: Types has no intrinsic value example: the paper currency we use
1. Fiat money has no intrinsic value example: the paper currency we use 2. Commodity money has intrinsic value examples: gold coins, cigarettes in P.O.W. camps Again, this material should be review for most students. Note: Many students have seen the film The Shawshank Redemption starring Tim Robbins and Morgan Freeman. Most of this film takes place in a prison. The prisoners have an informal “underground economy” in which cigarettes are used as money, even by prisoners who don’t smoke. Students who have seen the film will better understand “commodity money” if you mention this example. Also, the textbook (p.82) has a case study on cigarettes being used as money in POW camps during WWII.
9
NOW YOU TRY: Discussion Question
Which of these are money? a. Currency b. Checks c. Deposits in checking accounts (“demand deposits”) d. Credit cards e. Certificates of deposit (“time deposits”) You might want to ask students to determine, for each item listed, which of the functions of money it serves. Answers: a - yes b - no, not the checks themselves, but the funds in checking accounts are money. c - yes (see b) d - no, credit cards are a means of deferring payment. e - CDs are a store of value, and they are measured in money units. They are not readily spendable, though.
10
The money supply and monetary policy definitions
The money supply is the quantity of money available in the economy. Monetary policy is the control over the money supply. Again, this is mostly review.
11
The Federal Reserve Building Washington, DC
The central bank Monetary policy is conducted by a country’s central bank. In the U.S., the central bank is called the Federal Reserve (“the Fed”). The Federal Reserve Building Washington, DC Again, this is mostly review.
12
Money supply measures, September 2010
symbol assets included amount ($ billions) $900 Currency C $1766 C + demand deposits, travelers’ checks, other checkable deposits M1 Source: Federal Reserve Board, H.6 release. Figures are seasonally adjusted. The most important thing that students should get from this slide is the following: Each successive measure of the money supply is BIGGER and LESS LIQUID than the one it follows. I.e., checking account deposits (in M1 but not C) are less liquid than currency. Money market deposit account and savings account balances (in M2 but not M1) are less liquid than demand deposits. Whether you require your students to learn the definitions of every component of each monetary aggregate is up to you. Most professors agree that students should learn the definitions of M1, M2, demand deposits, and time deposits. Some professors feel that, since the quantity of information students can learn in a semester is finite, it is not worthwhile to require students to learn such terms as “repurchase agreements.” However, you might verbally state the definitions of such terms to help students better understand the nature of the monetary aggregates. $8709 M1 + small time deposits, savings deposits, money market mutual funds, money market deposit accounts M2
13
The Quantity Theory of Money
A simple theory linking the inflation rate to the growth rate of the money supply. Begins with the concept of velocity…
14
Velocity basic concept: the rate at which money circulates
definition: the number of times the average dollar bill changes hands in a given time period example: In 2009, $500 billion in transactions money supply = $100 billion The average dollar is used in five transactions in 2009 So, velocity = 5 In order for $500 billion in transactions to occur when the money supply is only $100b, each dollar must be used, on average, in five transactions.
15
Velocity, cont. This suggests the following definition: where
V = velocity T = value of all transactions M = money supply
16
Velocity, cont. Use nominal GDP as a proxy for total transactions.
Then, where P = price of output (GDP deflator) Y = quantity of output (real GDP) P Y = value of output (nominal GDP) You might ask students if they know the difference between nominal GDP and the value of transactions. Answer: nominal GDP includes the value of purchases of final goods; total transactions also includes the value of intermediate goods. Even though they are different, they are highly correlated. Also, our models focus on GDP, and there’s lots of great data on GDP. So from this point on, we’ll use the income version of velocity.
17
The quantity equation The quantity equation M V = P Y follows from the preceding definition of velocity. It is an identity: it holds by definition of the variables.
18
Money demand and the quantity equation
M/P = real money balances, the purchasing power of the money supply. A simple money demand function: (M/P )d = k Y where k = how much money people wish to hold for each dollar of income (k is exogenous)
19
Money demand and the quantity equation
money demand: (M/P )d = k Y quantity equation: M V = P Y The connection between them: k = 1/V When people hold lots of money relative to their incomes (k is large), money changes hands infrequently (V is small).
20
Back to the quantity theory of money
starts with quantity equation assumes V is constant & exogenous: Then, quantity equation becomes:
21
The quantity theory of money, cont.
How the price level is determined: With V constant, the money supply determines nominal GDP (P Y ). Real GDP is determined by the economy’s supplies of K and L and the production function (Chap 3). The price level is P = (nominal GDP)/(real GDP). It’s worthwhile to underscore the order (logical order, though not necessarily chronological order) in which variables are determined in this model (as well as the other models students will learn in this course). First, real GDP is already determined outside this model (real GDP is determined by the model from chapter 3, which was completely independent of the money supply or velocity or other nominal variables). Second, the Quantity Theory of money determines nominal GDP. Third, the values of nominal GDP (PY) and real GDP (Y) together determine P (as a ratio of PY to Y). If, on an exam or homework problem, students forget the logical order in which endogenous variables are determined --- or on a more fundamental level, forget which variables are endogenous and which are exogenous --- then they are much less likely to earn the high grades that most of them desire. [Note the similarity between the way P is determined and the definition of the GDP deflator from chapter 2.]
22
The quantity theory of money, cont.
Recall from Chapter 2: The growth rate of a product equals the sum of the growth rates. The quantity equation in growth rates:
23
The quantity theory of money, cont.
(Greek letter “pi”) denotes the inflation rate: The result from the preceding slide: Solve this result for :
24
The quantity theory of money, cont.
Normal economic growth requires a certain amount of money supply growth to facilitate the growth in transactions. Money growth in excess of this amount leads to inflation. The text on this slide is an intuitive way to understand the equation. For students that are more comfortable with concrete numerical examples, you could offer the following: Suppose real GDP is growing by 3% per year over the long run. Thus, production, income, and spending are all growing by 3%. This means that the volume of transactions will be growing as well. The central bank can achieve zero inflation (on average over the long run) simply by setting the growth rate of the money supply at 3%, in which case exactly enough new money is being supplied to facilitate the growth in transactions.
25
The quantity theory of money, cont.
Y/Y depends on growth in the factors of production and on technological progress (all of which we take as given, for now). Hence, the Quantity Theory predicts a one-for-one relation between changes in the money growth rate and changes in the inflation rate. Note: the theory doesn’t predict that the inflation rate will equal the money growth rate. It *does* predict that a change in the money growth rate will cause an equal change in the inflation rate.
26
Confronting the quantity theory with data
The quantity theory of money implies: 1. Countries with higher money growth rates should have higher inflation rates. 2. The long-run trend behavior of a country’s inflation should be similar to the long-run trend in the country’s money growth rate. Are the data consistent with these implications?
27
International data on inflation and money growth
Belarus Indonesia Inflation rate (percent, logarithmic scale) Turkey Ecuador Argentina Singapore Figure 4-2, p.92 Each variable is measured as an annual average over the period The strong positive correlation is evidence for the Quantity Theory of Money. Source: International Financial Statistics. Money supply growth (percent, logarithmic scale)
28
U.S. inflation and money growth, 1960-2010
M2 growth rate The quantity theory of money is intended to explain the long-run relation of inflation and money growth, not the short-run relation. In the long run, inflation and money growth are positively related, as the theory predicts. (In the short run, however, inflation and money growth appear highly negatively correlated! One possible reason is that the causality is reversed in the short run: when inflation rises – or is expected to rise – the Fed cuts back on money growth. If the economy slumps and inflation falls, the Fed increases money growth. It might be appropriate to discuss this when covering the chapters on short-run fluctuations.) source: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis inflation rate
29
U.S. inflation and money growth, 1960-2010
Inflation and money growth have the same long-run trends, as the Quantity Theory predicts. The quantity theory of money is intended to explain the long-run relation of inflation and money growth, not the short-run relation. In the long run, inflation and money growth are positively related, as the theory predicts. (In the short run, however, inflation and money growth appear highly negatively correlated! One possible reason is that the causality is reversed in the short run: when inflation rises – or is expected to rise – the Fed cuts back on money growth. If the economy slumps and inflation falls, the Fed increases money growth. It might be appropriate to discuss this when covering the chapters on short-run fluctuations.) source: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
30
Seigniorage To spend more without raising taxes or selling bonds, the govt can print money. The “revenue” raised from printing money is called seigniorage (pronounced SEEN-your-idge). The inflation tax: Printing money to raise revenue causes inflation. Inflation is like a tax on people who hold money. Introduction of abbreviation “govt” for “government” It’s quicker and easier for students to write “govt” in their notes. In the U.S., seigniorage accounts for only about 3% of total government revenue. In Italy and Greece, seigniorage has often been more than 10% of total revenue. In countries experiencing hyperinflation, seigniorage is often the government’s main source of revenue, and the need to print money to finance government expenditure is a primary cause of hyperinflation. See Case Study on p.93 “Paying for the American Revolution.”
31
Inflation and interest rates
Nominal interest rate, i not adjusted for inflation Real interest rate, r adjusted for inflation: r = i This is probably review, if your students have taken an introductory course in economics.
32
The Fisher effect The Fisher equation: i = r +
Chap 3: S = I determines r . Hence, an increase in causes an equal increase in i. This one-for-one relationship is called the Fisher effect. Note that S and I are real variables. In chapter 3, we learned about the factors that determine S and I. These factors did not include the money supply, velocity, inflation, or other nominal variables. Hence, in the classical (long-run) theory covered here in Chapter 4, changes in money growth or inflation do not affect the real interest rate. This is why there’s a one-for-one relationship between changes in the inflation rate and changes in the nominal interest rate. (Again, the Fisher effect does not imply that the nominal interest rate equals the inflation rate. It implies that changes in the nominal interest rate equal changes in the inflation rate, given a constant value of the real interest rate.)
33
U.S. inflation and nominal interest rates, 1960-2010
The data are consistent with the Fisher effect: inflation and the nominal interest rate are very highly correlated. However, they are not perfectly correlated, which absolutely does not invalidate the Fisher effect. Over time, the saving and investment curves move around, causing the real interest rate to move, which, in turn, causes the nominal interest rate to change for a given value of inflation. About the data: The inflation rate is the percentage change in the CPI from 12 months earlier. The nominal interest rate is the 3-month Treasury bill rate in the secondary market. Data obtained from inflation rate
34
Inflation and nominal interest rates across countries
Nominal interest rate (percent, logarithmic scale) Georgia Romania Zimbabwe Turkey Brazil Israel Kenya Source: same as textbook Each variable is measured as an annual average over The nominal interest rate is the rate on short-term government debt. U.S. Ethiopia Germany Inflation rate (percent, logarithmic scale)
35
NOW YOU TRY: Applying the theory
Suppose V is constant, M is growing 5% per year, Y is growing 2% per year, and r = 4. a. Solve for i. b. If the Fed increases the money growth rate by 2 percentage points per year, find i. c. Suppose the growth rate of Y falls to 1% per year. What will happen to ? What must the Fed do if it wishes to keep constant? This exercise gives students an immediate application of the Quantity Theory of Money and the Fisher effect. The math is not difficult.
36
Answers---the details:
NOW YOU TRY: Answers V is constant, M grows 5% per year, Y grows 2% per year, r = 4. a. First, find = 5 2 = 3. Then, find i = r + = = 7. b. i = 2, same as the increase in the money growth rate. c. If the Fed does nothing, = 1. To prevent inflation from rising, Fed must reduce the money growth rate by 1 percentage point per year. Answers---the details: a. First, we need to find . Constant velocity implies = (M/M) - (Y/Y) = = 3. Then, i = r + = = 7. b. Changes in the money growth rate do not affect real GDP or its growth rate. So, a two-point increase in money growth causes a two-point increase in inflation. According to the Fisher effect, the nominal interest rate should rise by the increase in inflation: two points (from i=7 to i=9). c. = (M/M) - (Y/Y). If (Y/Y) falls by 1 point, then will increase by 1 point; the Fed can prevent this by reducing (M/M) by 1 point. Intuition: With slower growth in the economy, the volume of transactions will be growing more slowly, which means that the need for new money will grow more slowly.
37
Two real interest rates
Notation: = actual inflation rate (not known until after it has occurred) E = expected inflation rate Two real interest rates: i – E = ex ante real interest rate: the real interest rate people expect at the time they buy a bond or take out a loan i – = ex post real interest rate: the real interest rate actually realized *** ATTENTION *** Mankiw has changed the notation for the expected inflation rate. He is now using the expectation operator E. Old notation from previous edition: e New notation starting in 7th edition: E When he wrote the new chapter on dynamic aggregate demand and dynamic aggregate supply, he used the expectation operator rather than the “e” superscript. He then decided to go back throughout the whole book and use the expectation operator consistently in all chapters.
38
Money demand and the nominal interest rate
In the quantity theory of money, the demand for real money balances depends only on real income Y. Another determinant of money demand: the nominal interest rate, i. the opportunity cost of holding money (instead of bonds or other interest-earning assets). Hence, i in money demand. The concept of “money demand” can be a bit awkward for students the first time they learn it. A good way to explain it is to imagine that a consumer has a certain amount of wealth, which is divided between money and other assets. The other assets typically generate some type of income (e.g. interest income in the case of bonds), but are much less liquid than money. There is therefore a trade-off: the more money the consumer holds in his portfolio, the more interest income he foregoes; the less money he holds, the more interest income he makes, but the less liquid is his portfolio. With this for background, a consumer’s “money demand” refers to the fraction of his wealth he would like to hold in the form of money (as opposed to less-liquid income-generating assets like bonds).
39
The money demand function
(M/P )d = real money demand, depends negatively on i i is the opp. cost of holding money positively on Y higher Y more spending so, need more money (“L” is used for the money demand function because money is the most liquid asset.) An increase in the nominal interest rate represents the increase in the opportunity cost of holding money rather than bonds, and would motivate the typical consumer to hold less of his wealth in the form of money, and more in the form of bonds (or other interest-earning assets). An increase in real income (other things equal) causes an increase in the consumer’s consumption and therefore spending. To facilitate this extra spending, the consumer will require more money. Thus, the consumer would like a larger fraction of his wealth to be in the form of money (rather than bonds, etc). This might involve redeeming some of his bonds. Or it might simply involve holding the additional income in the form of money rather than putting it into bonds.
40
The money demand function
When people are deciding whether to hold money or bonds, they don’t know what inflation will turn out to be. Hence, the nominal interest rate relevant for money demand is r + E.
41
The supply of real money balances
Equilibrium The supply of real money balances Real money demand
42
What determines what variable how determined (in the long run)
M exogenous (the Fed) r adjusts to ensure S = I Y P adjusts to ensure Again, it is very important for students to learn the logical order in which variables are determined. I.e., you do not need to know P in order to determine Y. You do need to know Y in order to determine L, and you need to know L and M in order to determine P.
43
How P responds to M For given values of r, Y, and E ,
a change in M causes P to change by the same percentage – just like in the quantity theory of money. This slide shows the connection between the money market equilibrium condition and the (simpler) Quantity Theory of Money, presented earlier in this chapter.
44
What about expected inflation?
Over the long run, people don’t consistently over- or under-forecast inflation, so E = on average. In the short run, E may change when people get new information. EX: Fed announces it will increase M next year. People will expect next year’s P to be higher, so E rises. This affects P now, even though M hasn’t changed yet…. This slide and the next correspond to the subsection of Chapter 4 entitled “Future Money and Current Prices,” appearing on pp
45
How P responds to E For given values of r, Y, and M ,
46
NOW YOU TRY: Discussion Question
Why is inflation bad? What costs does inflation impose on society? List all the ones you can think of. Focus on the long run. Think like an economist. Many of the social costs of inflation are not hard to figure out, if students “think like an economist.” Suggestion: After you pose the question, don’t immediately ask for students to volunteer their answers. Instead, tell them to think about the question for a moment, jot down their answers, and THEN ask for volunteers. You will get more participation (quantity & quality) this way, especially from students who don’t consider themselves fast thinkers. After presenting the following slides (which describe the costs), see how many of the costs presented here were anticipated by the students’ responses to the question on this slide.
47
A common misperception
Common misperception: inflation reduces real wages This is true only in the short run, when nominal wages are fixed by contracts. (Chap. 3) In the long run, the real wage is determined by labor supply and the marginal product of labor, not the price level or inflation rate. Consider the data…
48
The CPI and Average Hourly Earnings, 1965-2009
900 $20 800 Real average hourly earnings in 2009 dollars, right scale 700 $15 600 1965 = 100 500 Hourly wage in May 2009 dollars $10 400 Nominal average hourly earnings, (1965 = 100) The CPI has risen tremendously over the past 45 years. However, nominal wages have risen by a roughly similar magnitude. If the common misperception were true, then the real wage should show exactly the opposite behavior as the CPI. It doesn’t. While the real wage is not constant - it varies within the range of $15 to $20 – it exhibits no downward long-term trend. (We, of course, wouldn’t expect the real wage to be constant over the long run – we would expect it to change in response to shifts in the labor supply and MPL curves.) If you taught with the previous edition of my PowerPoint slides for Mankiw, please note that the nominal wage here is measured as an index (1965=100) rather than in the more natural units of current dollars (as in the previous edition). The reason for the change is so that both series (nominal wage and CPI) are now measured in the same units and can be shown along the same vertical axis, which makes it possible to compare the magnitude of the increase in both series. The real wage, however, is measured in the more natural units of 2009 dollars (May 2009 dollars, to be precise) along the right-hand (secondary) vertical axis. source: BLS Obtained from: (AHETPI = average hourly earnings: total private industries) 300 $5 200 CPI (1965 = 100) 100 $0 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010
49
The classical view of inflation
The classical view: A change in the price level is merely a change in the units of measurement. Then, why is inflation a social problem?
50
The social costs of inflation
…fall into two categories: 1. costs when inflation is expected 2. costs when inflation is different than people had expected
51
The costs of expected inflation: 1. Shoeleather cost
def: the costs and inconveniences of reducing money balances to avoid the inflation tax. i real money balances Remember: In long run, inflation does not affect real income or real spending. So, same monthly spending but lower average money holdings means more frequent trips to the bank to withdraw smaller amounts of cash. Thanks to ATMs and internet banking, the shoeleather cost is likely to be very small.
52
The costs of expected inflation: 2. Menu costs
def: The costs of changing prices. Examples: cost of printing new menus cost of printing & mailing new catalogs The higher is inflation, the more frequently firms must change their prices and incur these costs.
53
The costs of expected inflation: 3. Relative price distortions
Firms facing menu costs change prices infrequently. Example: A firm issues new catalog each January. As the general price level rises throughout the year, the firm’s relative price will fall. Different firms change their prices at different times, leading to relative price distortions… …causing microeconomic inefficiencies in the allocation of resources.
54
The costs of expected inflation: 4. Unfair tax treatment
Some taxes are not adjusted to account for inflation, such as the capital gains tax. Example: Jan 1: you buy $10,000 worth of IBM stock Dec 31: you sell the stock for $11,000, so your nominal capital gain is $1000 (10%). Suppose = 10% during the year. Your real capital gain is $0. But the govt requires you to pay taxes on your $1000 nominal gain!! In the 1970s, the income tax was not adjusted for inflation. There were a lot of people who received nominal salary increases large enough to push them into a higher tax bracket, but not large enough to prevent their real salaries from falling in the face of high inflation. This led to political pressure to index the income tax brackets. If inflation had been higher during , when lots of people were earning high capital gains, then there might have been more political pressure to index the capital gains tax.
55
The costs of expected inflation: 5. General inconvenience
Inflation makes it harder to compare nominal values from different time periods. This complicates long-range financial planning. Examples: Parents trying to decide how much to save for the future college expenses of their (now) young child. Thirty-somethings trying to decide how much to save for retirement. The CEO of a big corporation trying to decide whether to build a new factory, which will yield a revenue stream for 20 years or more. Your grandmother claiming that things were so much cheaper when she was your age. A silly digression: My grandmother used to have conversations like this with me, concluding that the dollar just isn’t worth what it was when she was young. I asked her “well, how much is a dollar worth today?”. She considered the question, and then offered her estimate: “About 60 cents.” I then offered her 60 cents for every dollar she has. She didn’t accept the offer. :)
56
Additional cost of unexpected inflation: Arbitrary redistribution of purchasing power
Many long-term contracts not indexed, but based on E . If turns out different from E , then some gain at others’ expense. Example: borrowers & lenders If > E , then (i ) < (i E ) and purchasing power is transferred from lenders to borrowers. If < E , then purchasing power is transferred from borrowers to lenders. Ask students this rhetorical question: Would it upset you if somebody arbitrarily took wealth away from some people and gave it to others? Well, this in effect is what’s happening when inflation turns out different than expected. Furthermore, it’s impossible to predict when inflation will turn out higher than expected, when it will be lower, and how big the difference will be. So, these redistributions of purchasing power are arbitrary and random. The text gives a simple numerical example on p.103. (In the short run, when many nominal wages are fixed by contracts, there are transfers of purchasing power between firms and their employees whenever inflation is different than expected when the contract was written and signed.)
57
Additional cost of high inflation: Increased uncertainty
When inflation is high, it’s more variable and unpredictable: turns out different from E more often, and the differences tend to be larger (though not systematically positive or negative) Arbitrary redistributions of wealth become more likely. This creates higher uncertainty, making risk averse people worse off.
58
One benefit of inflation
Nominal wages are rarely reduced, even when the equilibrium real wage falls. This hinders labor market clearing. Inflation allows the real wages to reach equilibrium levels without nominal wage cuts. Therefore, moderate inflation improves the functioning of labor markets. Students will better appreciate this point when they learn chapter 6 (the natural rate of unemployment). In this chapter, we will see how the failure of wages to adjust contributes to a long-term unemployment problem.
59
Hyperinflation Common definition: 50% per month
All the costs of moderate inflation described above become HUGE under hyperinflation. Money ceases to function as a store of value, and may not serve its other functions (unit of account, medium of exchange). People may conduct transactions with barter or a stable foreign currency. The bottom of p. 106 has an excellent example of life during a hyperinflation, which involves beer, a commodity with which your students may be somewhat familiar. See also the excellent case study on pp
60
What causes hyperinflation?
Hyperinflation is caused by excessive money supply growth: When the central bank prints money, the price level rises. If it prints money rapidly enough, the result is hyperinflation.
61
A few examples of hyperinflation
country period CPI Inflation % per year M2 Growth % per year Israel 338% 305% Brazil 1256% 1451% Bolivia 1818% 1727% Ukraine 2089% 1029% Argentina 2671% 1583% Dem. Republic of Congo / Zaire 3039% 2373% Angola 4145% 4106% Peru 5050% 3517% Zimbabwe 5316% 9914% source: World Development Indicators, World Bank. The textbook discusses a few examples of hyperinflation, including: 1. interwar Germany (data and discussion) Bolivia in 1985 (case study) Zimbabwe in (case study) This table provides data on the hyperinflations in Bolivia and Zimbabwe, and some additional examples. Notes: The inflation and money growth figures are computed from the end of the first year to the end of the last year shown in each “period.” During 2008, Zimbabwe’s hyperinflation continued and became spectacular. The table on this slide excludes 2008 data because it is missing from the WDI database. It’s easy to find estimates of Zimbabwe’s 2008 inflation, for example here: However, I cannot verify their reliability or find good data on Zimbabwe’s money supply in 2008. If you taught with a previous edition of my PowerPoints for Mankiw’s Macroeconomics, the slide like this one gave inflation and money growth as cumulative figures (over the period shown) rather than annual averages. Thus, it was a bit harder to compare, say, the two-year hyperinflation of Argentina with the six-year hyperinflation of Zaire. This slide, however, shows all inflation and money growth figures as annual averages over the period shown, which makes comparisons easier and just seems to make more sense. Also, compared to the corresponding slide in the previous edition of my PowerPoint slides for Mankiw, the set of countries included here is slightly different.
62
Why governments create hyperinflation
When a government cannot raise taxes or sell bonds, it must finance spending increases by printing money. In theory, the solution to hyperinflation is simple: stop printing money. In the real world, this requires drastic and painful fiscal restraint. Before revealing the contents of this slide, you might consider asking students the following question: “Solving the problem of hyperinflation is easy. Why, then, do governments allow hyperinflation to occur?”
63
The Classical Dichotomy
Real variables: Measured in physical units – quantities and relative prices, for example: quantity of output produced real wage: output earned per hour of work real interest rate: output earned in the future by lending one unit of output today Nominal variables: Measured in money units, e.g., nominal wage: Dollars per hour of work. nominal interest rate: Dollars earned in future by lending one dollar today. the price level: The amount of dollars needed to buy a representative basket of goods.
64
The Classical Dichotomy
Note: Real variables were explained in Chap 3, nominal ones in Chapter 4. Classical dichotomy: the theoretical separation of real and nominal variables in the classical model, which implies nominal variables do not affect real variables. Neutrality of money: Changes in the money supply do not affect real variables. In the real world, money is approximately neutral in the long run.
65
Chapter Summary Money def: the stock of assets used for transactions
functions: medium of exchange, store of value, unit of account types: commodity money (has intrinsic value), fiat money (no intrinsic value) money supply controlled by central bank Quantity theory of money assumes velocity is stable, concludes that the money growth rate determines the inflation rate. 64
66
Chapter Summary Nominal interest rate
equals real interest rate + inflation rate the opp. cost of holding money Fisher effect: Nominal interest rate moves one-for-one w/ expected inflation. Money demand depends only on income in the Quantity Theory also depends on the nominal interest rate if so, then changes in expected inflation affect the current price level. 65
67
Chapter Summary Costs of inflation
Expected inflation shoeleather costs, menu costs, tax & relative price distortions, inconvenience of correcting figures for inflation Unexpected inflation all of the above plus arbitrary redistributions of wealth between debtors and creditors 66
68
Chapter Summary Hyperinflation
caused by rapid money supply growth when money printed to finance govt budget deficits stopping it requires fiscal reforms to eliminate govt’s need for printing money 67
69
Chapter Summary Classical dichotomy
In classical theory, money is neutral--does not affect real variables. So, we can study how real variables are determined w/o reference to nominal ones. Then, money market eq’m determines price level and all nominal variables. Most economists believe the economy works this way in the long run. 68
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.