Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
1
Income and Substitution Effects
© 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
2
The (big) Plan Marshallian demand functions (recap) Income effect
Substitution effect Demand and demand curves Hicksian (compensated) demand and demand curves Slutsky decomposition: income- and price effects Marshallian- and compensated price elasticities Engel aggregation; Cournot aggregation [Consumer surplus and compensated variation (CV)] © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
3
Marshallian Demand Functions
UMP: The optimal levels of x1,x2,…,xn Can be expressed as n functions of all prices and income x1* = x1(p1,p2,…,pn,I) x2* = x2(p1,p2,…,pn,I) … xn* = xn(p1,p2,…,pn,I) © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
4
Marshallian Demand Functions
Indirect utility function V V(p1,p2,…,pn,I)=U(x1(p1,p2,…,pn,I),…, xn(p1,p2,…,pn,I)) Maximized utility for any given (p1,p2,…,pn,I) © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
5
Marshallian Demand Functions
For only two goods (x and y): x* = x(px,py,I) y* = y(px,py,I) Prices and income are exogenous The individual has no control over these parameters Query. In which situations does individual impact on prices? © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
6
Cobb-Douglas utility function:
5.1 Homogeneity Cobb-Douglas utility function: utility = U(x,y) = x0.3y0.7 The demand functions are: x*=0.3I/px and y*=0.7I/py Query. Homogeneity in prices and income CES utility function: utility = U(x,y) = x0.5 + y0.5 The demand functions are: Query. Homogeneity in prices and income © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
7
Income Effect: Changes in Income
An increase in income Will shift the budget line out in a parallel fashion px/py does not change The optimal MRS must stay constant as the individual moves to higher levels of satisfaction © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
8
Changes in Income Normal good Inferior good Over some range of income
A good xi for which ∂xi/∂I ≥0 over that range of income Inferior good A good xi for which ∂xi/∂I < 0 over that range of income Query. Relate consumption of junk food and high quality food to income! © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
9
Effect of an Increase in Income on the Quantities of x and y Chosen
5.1 Effect of an Increase in Income on the Quantities of x and y Chosen I3 Quantity of x Quantity of y U3 I2 U2 x3 y3 U1 x2 y2 I1 x1 y1 As income increases from I1 to I2 to I3, the optimal (utility-maximizing) choices of x and y are shown by the successively higher points of tangency. Observe that the budget constraint shifts in a parallel way because its slope (given by -px/py) does not change. © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
10
An Indifference Curve Map Exhibiting Inferiority
5.2 An Indifference Curve Map Exhibiting Inferiority Quantity of z Quantity of y U3 I3 z3 y3 I2 U2 z2 y2 I1 U1 z1 y1 In this diagram, good z is inferior because the quantity purchased decreases as income increases. Here, y is a normal good (as it must be if there are only two goods available), and purchases of y increase as total expenditures increase. © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
11
Changes in a Good’s Price
A change in the price of a good Alters the slope of the budget line (constraint) Changes the optimal MRS at the consumer’s utility-maximizing choices Two effects come into play Substitution effect Income effect in addition © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
12
Changes in a Good’s Price
Substitution effect of a price change Consumption patterns would be allocated so as to equate the MRS to the new price ratio Query. What about perfect substitutes? © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
13
Changes in a Good’s Price
Income effect of a price change Arises because a price change necessarily changes an individual’s real income The individual cannot stay on the initial indifference curve and must move to a new one © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
14
5.3 Demonstration of the Income and Substitution Effects of a Decrease in the Price of x When the price of x decreases from p1x to p2x , the utility-maximizing choice shifts from x*,y* to x**,y**. This movement can be broken down into two analytically different effects: first, the substitution effect, involving a movement along the initial indifference curve to point B, where the MRS is equal to the new price ratio; and second, the income effect, entailing a movement to a higher level of utility because real income has increased. In the diagram, both the substitution and income effects cause more x to be bought when its price decreases. Notice that point I/py is the same as before the price change; this is because py has not changed. Therefore, point I/py appears on both the old and new budget constraints. Quantity of x Quantity of y U2 I/py I=p2xx+pyy I=p1xx+pyy U1 y** x** y* x* B xB Substitution effect Income effect Total increase in x © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
15
5.4 Demonstration of the Income and Substitution Effects of an Increase in the Price of x When the price of x increases, the budget constraint shifts inward. The movement from the initial utility-maximizing point (x*,y*) to the new point (x**,y**) can be analyzed as two separate effects. The substitution effect would be depicted as a movement to point B on the initial indifference curve (U2). The price increase, however, would create a loss of purchasing power and a consequent movement to a lower indifference curve. This is the income effect. In the diagram, both the income and substitution effects cause the quantity of x to decrease as a result of the increase in its price. Again, the point I/py is not affected by the change in the price of x. Quantity of x Quantity of y I/py I=p1xx+pyy I=p2xx+pyy U1 U2 B xB y** x** y* x* Income effect Substitution effect Total decrease in x © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
16
Changes in a Good’s Price
If a good is normal, substitution and income effects reinforce one another When p : Substitution effect: quantity demanded Income effect: quantity demanded When p : Substitution effect: quantity demanded Income effect: quantity demanded © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
17
Changes in a Good’s Price
If a good is inferior, substitution and income effects move in opposite directions When p : Substitution effect: quantity demanded Income effect: quantity demanded When p : Substitution effect: quantity demanded Income effect: quantity demanded © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
18
Changes in a Good’s Price
Giffen’s paradox If the income effect of a price change is strong enough, there could be a positive relationship between price and quantity demanded An increase in price leads to a drop in real income Since the good is inferior, a drop in income causes quantity demanded to rise © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
19
Changes in a Good’s Price
For inferior goods, no definite prediction can be made for changes in price The substitution effect and income effect move in opposite directions If the income effect outweighs the substitution effect, we have a case of Giffen’s paradox © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
20
The Individual’s Demand Curve
An individual‘s Marshallian demand for x Depends on preferences, all prices, and income: x* = x(px,py,I) It is convenient to graph it assuming that income and the price of y (py) are held constant: demand curve © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
21
Construction of an Individual’s Marshallian Demand Curve
5.5 Construction of an Individual’s Marshallian Demand Curve Quantity of y Quantity of x Quantity of x px I = px’’’x + pyy I = px’x + pyy I / py I = px’’x + pyy U3 U2 U1 px’ x x’ px’’ x’’ x’ x” x”’ Px‘‘‘ x’’’ In (a), the individual’s utility-maximizing choices of x and y are shown for three different prices of x(p’x, p”x, and p’”x). In (b), this relationship between px and x is used to construct the demand curve for x. The demand curve is drawn on the assumption that py, I, and preferences remain constant as px varies. © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
22
The Individual’s Demand Curve
An individual demand curve Shows the relationship between the price of a good and the quantity of that good purchased by an individual Assuming that all other determinants of demand are held constant Visually graphs Marshallian demand, holding constant “other determinants” © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
23
The Individual’s Demand Curve
Shifts in the demand curve Three factors are held constant when a demand curve is derived Income Prices of other goods (py) The individual’s preferences If any of these factors change, the demand curve will shift to a new position demand :. quantity demanded © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
24
The Individual’s Demand Curve
A change in quantity demanded Movement along a given demand curve Caused by a change in the price of the good A change in demand Shift in the demand curve Caused by changes in income, prices of other goods, or preferences © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
25
5.2 Demand Functions and Demand Curves
Cobb-Douglas The demand functions: x=0.3I/px and y=0.7I/py For I=$100: x=30/px and y=70/py Or: pxx=30 and pyy=70 demand curves: simple hyperbolas An increase in income would shift both demand curves outward The demand curve for x is not shifted by changes in py and vice versa – Query: How is this possible? Income effect: neg as higher py lowers real income; subst positive, as higher py lowers y and raises x; both effects exactly cancel. © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
26
5.2 Demand Functions and Demand Curves
CES For good x: For I=$100 and py=1: x=100/(px2+px) General hyperbolic relationship between price and quantity consumed Increases in I or py would shift the demand curve for good x outward because: © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
27
Uncompensated /Compensated Demand Curves
Approach 1: Price change for given income level Marshallian = uncompensated demand curves As price increases, income fixed, utility declines Reactions to price changes include both income and substitution effects Approach 2: Price change for given utility level Hicksian = compensated demand curves As price increases, utility fixed, income increases Reactions to price changes include only substitution effects © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
28
Marshallian Demand Curves and Functions
Actual level of utility Varies along the demand curve As the price of x falls, the individual moves to higher indifference curves nominal income is held constant as the demand curve is derived real income rises as the price of x falls © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
29
Hicksian Demand Curves and Functions
Price change for given utility level Hold utility constant while examining reactions to changes in px effects of the price change are “compensated” by income changes so as to force the individual to remain on the same indifference curve Reactions to price changes include only substitution effects © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
30
Compensated Demand Curves and Functions
Compensated (Hicksian) demand curve Shows the relationship between the price of a good and the quantity purchased while other prices and utility are held constant (income adjusted) Is a two-dimensional representation of the compensated demand function (= solution of the EMP) x* = xc(px,py,U) © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
31
Construction of a Compensated Demand Curve
5.6 Construction of a Compensated Demand Curve Quantity of y Quantity of x Quantity of x px U2 Slope = p’x/py x’ Slope = p”x/py xc px’ x’ Slope = p”’x/py px’’ x’’ x” px’’’ x’’’ x”’ The curve xc shows how the quantity of x demanded changes when px changes, holding py and utility constant. That is, the individual’s income is ‘‘compensated’’ to keep utility constant. Hence xc reflects only substitution effects of changing prices. © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
32
Hicksian Demand Functions
Expenditure minimization problem (recap) Min expenditure: pxx+pyy s.t. U(x,y)≥Ū Lagrangian: ℒ =pxx+pyy+λ[U(x,y)-Ū] Solution: Hicksian demand functions: x(px,py, Ū) expenditure function: E(px,py, Ū) = px x(px,py, Ū) + py y(px,py, Ū) © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
33
Expenditure function and Hicksian Demand Functions
Shephard’s lemma Compensated demand function for a good Derived from the expenditure function Envelope theorem: © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
34
Compensated / Uncompensated Demand Curves
Relationship between compensated and uncompensated demand curves Normal good Compensated demand curve is less responsive to price changes than is the uncompensated demand curve Uncompensated demand curve reflects both income and substitution effects Compensated demand curve reflects only substitution effects © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
35
Comparison of Compensated and Uncompensated Demand Curves
5.7 Comparison of Compensated and Uncompensated Demand Curves Quantity of x px xc(px,py,U) x(px,py,I) px’ x’ x* px’’ x’’ px’’’ x** x’’’ The compensated (xc) and uncompensated (x) demand curves intersect at p”x because x” is demanded under each concept. For prices above p”x, the individual’s purchasing power must be increased with the compensated demand curve; thus, more x is demanded than with the uncompensated curve. For prices below p”x, purchasing power must be reduced for the compensated curve; therefore, less x is demanded than with the uncompensated curve. The standard demand curve is more price-responsive because it incorporates both substitution and income effects, whereas the curve xc reflects only substitution effects. © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
36
5.3 Compensated Demand Functions
The utility is: utility = U(x,y) = x0.5y0.5 The Marshallian demand functions: x(px,py,I) = 0.5I/px and y(px,py,I) = 0.5I/py Expenditure function: E(px,py, Ū)=2px0.5py0.5Ū Use Shephard’s lemma to calculate the compensated demand functions as © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
37
A Mathematical Development of Response to Price Changes
Consider two goods, x and y Important relationship between uncompensated and compensated demand Let U be an arbitrary utility level; I be minimum expenditure required to obtain that U: I = E(px,py,U) xc (px,py,U) = x [px,py,I] = x [px,py,E(px,py,U)] © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
38
A Mathematical Development of Response to Price Changes
Differentiate xc (px,py,U) = x [px,py,E(px,py,U)] with respect to px The substitution effect The first term: the slope of the compensated demand curve The income effect The second term: measures the way in which changes in px affect the demand for x through changes in purchasing power © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
39
A Mathematical Development of Response to Price Changes
The Slutsky equation © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
40
5.4 A Slutsky Decomposition
Marshallian demand function for good x x(px,py,I) = 0.5I/px Compensated demand function for this good xc(px,py, U)=px-0.5py0.5U Total effect of a price change on Marshallian demand © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
41
5.4 A Slutsky Decomposition
Query. Verify that total effect = SE + IE © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
42
Elasticities Changes in prices or income ☞ change in demand
absolute changes depend on units of measurement elasticities: %-measure, independent of units Elasticities not restricted to demand changes due to price/income changes between any two variables © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
43
Marshallian Demand Elasticities
Marshallian demand function: x(px,py,I) 1. Price elasticity of demand, ex, px Measures the proportionate change in quantity demanded In response to a proportionate change in a good’s own price © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
44
Marshallian Demand Elasticities
2. Income elasticity of demand, ex,I Measures the proportionate change in quantity demanded In response to a proportionate change in income © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
45
Marshallian Demand Elasticities
3. Cross-price elasticity of demand, ex,py Measures the proportionate change in quantity of x demanded In response to a proportionate change in the price of some other good (y) Query. In which case is the cross-price elasticity equal to zero? If IE = SE (for price increase of other good) – Cobb Douglas case! © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
46
Price elasticity of demand
The own price elasticity of demand is always negative exception is Giffen’s paradox The size of the elasticity is important If ex,px < -1, demand is elastic If ex,px > -1, demand is inelastic If ex,px = -1, demand is unit elastic Query. Why is size important? If you increase price to raise revenue – revenue only increases when elasticity is low. © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
47
Price Elasticity of Demand
Total spending on x = pxx If ex,px > -1, demand is inelastic Price and total spending move in the same direction If ex,px < -1, demand is elastic Price and total spending move in opposite directions © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
48
Compensated Price Elasticities
Compensated demand function, xc(px,py,U) Compensated own-price elasticity of demand, exc,px Measures the proportionate compensated change in quantity demanded In response to a proportionate change in a good’s own price © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
49
Compensated Price Elasticities
2. Compensated cross-price elasticity of demand, exc,py Measures the proportionate compensated change in quantity of x demanded In response to a proportionate change in the price of another good, y © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
50
Compensated Price Elasticities
© 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
51
Compensated Price Elasticities
Slutsky equation: compensated and uncompensated price elasticities will be similar if The share of income devoted to x is small The income elasticity of x is small Sure, if income effect is small then the elasticities are similar © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
52
Relationships among Demand Elasticities
Homogeneity Demand functions are homogeneous of degree zero in all prices and income Euler’s theorem for homogenous functions shows that © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
53
Relationships among Demand Elasticities
Engel aggregation Engel’s law: income elasticity of demand for food items is <1 Income elasticity of demand for all nonfood items must be >1 Differentiate the budget constraint with respect to income © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
54
Relationships among Demand Elasticities
Cournot aggregation The size of the cross-price effect of a change in px on the quantity of y consumed is restricted because of the budget constraint Differentiate the budget constraint with respect to px © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
55
Relationships among Demand Elasticities
Cournot aggregation First, multiply with px/I © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
56
5.5 Demand Elasticities: The Importance of Substitution Effects
Cobb-Douglas: U(x,y)=xαyβ, α+β=1 Demand functions: x(px,py,I)=αI/px, and y(px,py,I)=βI/py=(1- α)I/py Elasticities: © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
57
Cobb-Douglas: 5.5 Demand Elasticities Because sx = α and sy = β
© 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
58
5.5 Demand Elasticities: The Importance of Substitution Effects
Cobb-Douglas: Using the Slutsky equation in elasticity form to derive the compensated price elasticity: © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
59
Application: Welfare Change (CV)
Measure the change in welfare That an individual experiences if the price of good x increases from p0x to p1x To reach U0 Expenditure at p0x: E(p0x,py,U0) Expenditure at p1x: E(p1x,py,U0) To compensate for the price increase – compensating variation (CV) of: CV = E(px1,py,U0) - E(px0,py,U0) © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
60
5.8 (a) Indifference curve map
Showing Compensating Variation Spending on other goods ($) Quantity of x E(p1x,py,U0) CV U0 E(p0x,py,U0) U1 E(p0x,py,U0) y1 x1 y2 x2 y0 x0 If the price of x increases from p0x to p1x, this person needs extra expenditures of CV to remain on the U0 indifference curve. Integration shows that CV can also be represented by the shaded area below the compensated demand curve in panel (b). © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
61
5.8 (b) Compensated demand curve
Showing Compensating Variation Price Quantity of x x1 x0 xc(px,…,U0) p2x p1x B p0x A If the price of x increases from p0x to p1x, this person needs extra expenditures of CV to remain on the U0 indifference curve. Integration shows that CV can also be represented by the shaded area below the compensated demand curve in panel (b). © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
62
Relationships among Demand Concepts
© 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
Similar presentations
© 2024 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.