Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers"— Presentation transcript:

1 Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers
Chapter 11: Dynamic Games

2 Chapter 11: Dynamic Games
Introduction In a wide variety of markets firms compete sequentially one firm makes a move new product advertising second firms sees this move and responds These are dynamic games may create a first-mover advantage or may give a second-mover advantage may also allow early mover to preempt the market Can generate very different equilibria from simultaneous move games Chapter 11: Dynamic Games

3 Chapter 11: Dynamic Games
Stackelberg Interpret first in terms of Cournot Firms choose outputs sequentially leader sets output first, and visibly follower then sets output The firm moving first has a leadership advantage can anticipate the follower’s actions can therefore manipulate the follower For this to work the leader must be able to commit to its choice of output Strategic commitment has value Chapter 11: Dynamic Games

4 Stackelberg equilibrium
Assume that there are two firms with identical products As in our earlier Cournot example, let demand be: P = A – B.Q = A – B(q1 + q2) Marginal cost for for each firm is c Firm 1 is the market leader and chooses q1 In doing so it can anticipate firm 2’s actions So consider firm 2. Residual demand for firm 2 is: P = (A – Bq1) – Bq2 Marginal revenue therefore is: MR2 = (A - Bq1) – 2Bq2 Chapter 11: Dynamic Games

5 Stackelberg equilibrium 2
Equate marginal revenue with marginal cost This is firm 2’s best response function MR2 = (A - Bq1) – 2Bq2 But firm 1 knows what q2 is going to be q2 Firm 1 knows that this is how firm 2 will react to firm 1’s output choice MC = c From earlier example we know that this is the monopoly output. This is an important result. The Stackelberg leader chooses the same output as a monopolist would. But firm 2 is not excluded from the market  q*2 = (A - c)/2B - q1/2 So firm 1 can anticipate firm 2’s reaction Demand for firm 1 is: P = (A - Bq2) – Bq1 (A – c)/2B P = (A - Bq*2) – Bq1 Equate marginal revenue with marginal cost P = (A - (A-c)/2) – Bq1/2 S (A – c)/4B  P = (A + c)/2 – Bq1/2 Solve this equation for output q1 R2 Marginal revenue for firm 1 is: q1 MR1 = (A + c)/2 - Bq1 (A – c)/B (A – c)/2 (A + c)/2 – Bq1 = c  q*1 = (A – c)/2  q*2 = (A – c)4B Chapter 11: Dynamic Games

6 Stackelberg equilibrium 3
Leadership benefits the leader firm 1 but harms the follower firm 2 Aggregate output is 3(A-c)/4B Leadership benefits consumers but reduces aggregate profits q2 So the equilibrium price is (A+3c)/4 Firm 1’s best response function is “like” firm 2’s (A-c)/B Firm 1’s profit is (A-c)2/8B R1 Compare this with the Cournot equilibrium Firm 2’s profit is (A-c)2/16B We know that the Cournot equilibrium is: (A-c)/2B qC1 = qC2 = (A-c)/3B C (A-c)/3B S The Cournot price is (A+c)/3 (A-c)/4B R2 Profit to each firm is (A-c)2/9B q1 (A-c)/3B (A-c)/ B (A-c)/2B Chapter 11: Dynamic Games

7 Stackelberg and commitment
It is crucial that the leader can commit to its output choice without such commitment firm 2 should ignore any stated intent by firm 1 to produce (A – c)/2B units the only equilibrium would be the Cournot equilibrium So how to commit? prior reputation investment in additional capacity place the stated output on the market Given such a commitment, the timing of decisions matters But is moving first always better than following? Consider price competition Chapter 11: Dynamic Games

8 Stackelberg and price competition
With price competition matters are different first-mover does not have an advantage suppose products are identical suppose first-mover commits to a price greater than marginal cost the second-mover will undercut this price and take the market so the only equilibrium is P = MC identical to simultaneous game now suppose that products are differentiated perhaps as in the spatial model suppose that there are two firms as in Chapter 10 but now firm 1 can set and commit to its price first we know the demands to the two firms and we know the best response function of firm 2 Chapter 11: Dynamic Games

9 Stackelberg and price competition 2
Demand to firm 1 is D1(p1, p2) = N(p2 – p1 + t)/2t Demand to firm 2 is D2(p1, p2) = N(p1 – p2 + t)/2t Best response function for firm 2 is p*2 = (p1 + c + t)/2 Firm 1 knows this so demand to firm 1 is D1(p1, p*2) = N(p*2 – p1 + t)/2t = N(c +3t – p1)/4t Profit to firm 1 is then π1 = N(p1 – c)(c + 3t – p1)/4t Differentiate with respect to p1: π1/p1 = N(c + 3t – p1 – p1 + c)/4t = N(2c + 3t – 2p1)/4t Solving this gives: p*1 = c + 3t/2 Chapter 11: Dynamic Games

10 Stackelberg and price competition 3
p*1 = c + 3t/2 Substitute into the best response function for firm 2 p*2 = (p*1 + c + t)/2  p*2 = c + 5t/4 Prices are higher than in the simultaneous case: p* = c + t Firm 1 sets a higher price than firm 2 and so has lower market share: c + 3t/2 + txm = c + 5t/4 + t(1 – xm)  xm = 3/8 Profit to firm 1 is then π1 = 18Nt/32 Profit to firm 2 is π2 = 25Nt/32 Price competition gives a second mover advantage. Chapter 11: Dynamic Games

11 Dynamic games and credibility
The dynamic games above require that firms move in sequence and that they can commit to the moves reasonable with quantity less obvious with prices with no credible commitment solution of a dynamic game becomes very different Cournot first-mover cannot maintain output Bertrand firm cannot maintain price Consider a market entry game can a market be pre-empted by a first-mover? Chapter 11: Dynamic Games

12 Credibility and predation
Take a simple example two companies Microhard (incumbent) and Newvel (entrant) Newvel makes its decision first enter or stay out of Microhard’s market Microhard then chooses accommodate or fight pay-off matrix is as follows: Chapter 11: Dynamic Games

13 An example of predation
What is the equilibrium for this game? An example of predation But is (Enter, Fight) credible? The Pay-Off Matrix There appear to be two equilibria to this game Microhard (Enter, Fight) is not an equilibrium Fight Accommodate (Stay Out, Accommodate) is not an equilibrium (0, 0) Enter (0, 0) (2, 2) Newvel (1, 5) Stay Out (1, 5) (1, 5) Chapter 11: Dynamic Games

14 Credibility and predation 2
Options listed are strategies not actions Microhard’s option to Fight is not an action It is a strategy Microhard will fight if Newvel enters but otherwise remains placid Similarly, Accommodate is a strategy defines actions to take depending on Newvel’s strategic choice Are the actions called for by a particular strategy credible Is the promise to Fight if Newvel enters believable If not, then the associated equilibrium is suspect The matrix-form ignores timing. represent the game in its extensive form to highlight sequence of moves Chapter 11: Dynamic Games

15 The example again What if Newvel decides to Enter? Fight is eliminated
Microhard is better to Accommodate (0,0) (0,0) Fight Fight (2,2) Accommodate Enter Enter M2 Enter, Accommodate is the unique equilibrium for this game (2,2) Newvel Newvel will choose to Enter since Microhard will Accommodate N1 Stay Out (1,5) Chapter 11: Dynamic Games

16 The chain-store paradox
What if Microhard competes in more than one market? threatening in one market one may affect the others But: Selten’s Chain-Store Paradox arises 20 markets established sequentially will Microhard “fight” in the first few as a means to prevent entry in later ones? No: this is the paradox Suppose Microhard “fights” in the first 19 markets, will it “fight” in the 20th? With just one market left, we are in the same situation as before “Enter, Accommodate” becomes the only equilibrium Fighting in the 20th market won’t help in subsequent markets . . There are no subsequent markets So, “fight” strategy will not be adapted in the 20th market Chapter 11: Dynamic Games

17 The chain-store paradox 2
Now consider the 19th market Equilibrium for this market would be “Enter, Accommodate” The only reason to adopt “Fight” in the 19th market is to convince a potential entrant in the 20th market that Microhard is a “fighter” But Microhard will not “Fight” in the 20th market So “Enter, Accommodate” becomes the unique equilibrium for this market, too What about the 18th market? “Fight” only to influence entrants in the 19th and 20th markets But the threat to “Fight” in these markets is not credible. “Enter, Accommodate” is again the equilibrium By repetition, we see that Microhard will not “Fight” in any market Chapter 11: Dynamic Games


Download ppt "Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers"

Similar presentations


Ads by Google