Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
1
Chapter 7 Revealed Preference
2
Revealed Preference Analysis
Suppose we observe the demands (consumption choices) that a consumer makes for different budgets. This reveals information about the consumer’s preferences. We can use this information to ...
3
Revealed Preference Analysis
Test the behavioral hypothesis that a consumer chooses the most preferred bundle from those available. Discover the consumer’s preference relation.
4
Assumptions on Preferences
do not change while the choice data are gathered. are strictly convex. are monotonic. Together, convexity and monotonicity imply that the most preferred affordable bundle is unique.
5
Assumptions on Preferences
x2 If preferences are convex and monotonic (i.e. well-behaved) then the most preferred affordable bundle is unique. x2* x1* x1
6
Direct Preference Revelation
Suppose that the bundle x* is chosen when the bundle y is affordable. Then x* is revealed directly as preferred to y (otherwise y would have been chosen).
7
Direct Preference Revelation
x2 The chosen bundle x* is revealed directly as preferred to the bundles y and z. x* z y x1
8
Direct Preference Revelation
That x is revealed directly as preferred to y will be written as x y. D p
9
Indirect Preference Revelation
Suppose x is revealed directly preferred to y, and y is revealed directly preferred to z. Then, by transitivity, x is revealed indirectly as preferred to z. Write this as x z so x y and y z x z. p I D p D p p I
10
Indirect Preference Revelation
x2 z is not affordable when x* is chosen. x* z x1
11
Indirect Preference Revelation
x2 x* is not affordable when y* is chosen. x* y* z x1
12
Indirect Preference Revelation
x2 z is not affordable when x* is chosen. x* is not affordable when y* is chosen. x* y* z x1
13
Indirect Preference Revelation
x2 z is not affordable when x* is chosen. x* is not affordable when y* is chosen So x* and z cannot be compared directly. x* y* z x1
14
Indirect Preference Revelation
x2 z is not affordable when x* is chosen. x* is not affordable when y* is chosen So x* and z cannot be compared directly. x* But x*x* y* D p y* z x1
15
Indirect Preference Revelation
x2 z is not affordable when x* is chosen. x* is not affordable when y* is chosen So x* and z cannot be compared directly. x* But x*x* y* and y* z D p y* z D p x1
16
Indirect Preference Revelation
x2 z is not affordable when x* is chosen. x* is not affordable when y* is chosen So x* and z cannot be compared directly. x* But x*x* y* and y* z so x* z. D p y* z D p p x1 I
17
Two Axioms of Revealed Preference
To apply revealed preference analysis, choices must satisfy two criteria -- the Weak and the Strong Axioms of Revealed Preference.
18
The Weak Axiom of Revealed Preference (WARP)
If the bundle x is revealed directly as preferred to the bundle y then it is never the case that y is revealed directly as preferred to x; i.e x y not (y x). D p D p
19
The Weak Axiom of Revealed Preference (WARP)
Choice data which violate the WARP are inconsistent with economic rationality. The WARP is a necessary condition for applying economic rationality to explain observed choices.
20
The Weak Axiom of Revealed Preference (WARP)
What choice data violate the WARP?
21
The Weak Axiom of Revealed Preference (WARP)
y x x1
22
The Weak Axiom of Revealed Preference (WARP)
x is chosen when y is available so x y. D p y x x1
23
The Weak Axiom of Revealed Preference (WARP)
x is chosen when y is available so x y. D p y is chosen when x is available so y x. D p y x x1
24
The Weak Axiom of Revealed Preference (WARP)
x is chosen when y is available so x y. D p y is chosen when x is available so y x. D p These statements are inconsistent with each other. y x x1
25
Checking if Data Violate the WARP
A consumer makes the following choices: At prices (p1,p2)=($2,$2) the choice was (x1,x2) = (10,1). At (p1,p2)=($2,$1) the choice was (x1,x2) = (5,5). At (p1,p2)=($1,$2) the choice was (x1,x2) = (5,4). Is the WARP violated by these data?
26
Checking if Data Violate the WARP
27
Checking if Data Violate the WARP
Red numbers are costs of chosen bundles.
28
Checking if Data Violate the WARP
Circles surround affordable bundles that were not chosen.
29
Checking if Data Violate the WARP
Circles surround affordable bundles that were not chosen.
30
Checking if Data Violate the WARP
Circles surround affordable bundles that were not chosen.
31
Checking if Data Violate the WARP
32
Checking if Data Violate the WARP
33
Checking if Data Violate the WARP
(10,1) is directly revealed preferred to (5,4), but (5,4) is directly revealed preferred to (10,1), so the WARP is violated by the data.
34
Checking if Data Violate the WARP
x2 (5,4) (10,1) D p (10,1) (5,4) D p x1
35
The Strong Axiom of Revealed Preference (SARP)
If the bundle x is revealed (directly or indirectly) as preferred to the bundle y and x ¹ y, then it is never the case that the y is revealed (directly or indirectly) as preferred to x; i.e x y or x y D p I p not ( y x or y x ). D p p I
36
The Strong Axiom of Revealed Preference
What choice data would satisfy the WARP but violate the SARP?
37
The Strong Axiom of Revealed Preference
Consider the following data: A: (p1,p2,p3) = (1,3,10) & (x1,x2,x3) = (3,1,4) B: (p1,p2,p3) = (4,3,6) & (x1,x2,x3) = (2,5,3) C: (p1,p2,p3) = (1,1,5) & (x1,x2,x3) = (4,4,3)
38
The Strong Axiom of Revealed Preference
B: ($4,$3,$6) (2,5,3). C: ($1,$1,$5) (4,4,3).
39
The Strong Axiom of Revealed Preference
40
The Strong Axiom of Revealed Preference
In situation A, bundle A is directly revealed preferred to bundle C; A C. D p
41
The Strong Axiom of Revealed Preference
In situation B, bundle B is directly revealed preferred to bundle A; B A. D p
42
The Strong Axiom of Revealed Preference
In situation C, bundle C is directly revealed preferred to bundle B; C B. D p
43
The Strong Axiom of Revealed Preference
44
The Strong Axiom of Revealed Preference
The data do not violate the WARP.
45
The Strong Axiom of Revealed Preference
We have that A C, B A and C B so, by transitivity, A B, B C and C A. D p D p D p I p I p I p The data do not violate the WARP but ...
46
The Strong Axiom of Revealed Preference
We have that A C, B A and C B so, by transitivity, A B, B C and C A. D p D p D p I I I p I p I p I The data do not violate the WARP but ...
47
The Strong Axiom of Revealed Preference
B A is inconsistent with A B. D p I p I I I The data do not violate the WARP but ...
48
The Strong Axiom of Revealed Preference
A C is inconsistent with C A. D p I p I I I The data do not violate the WARP but ...
49
The Strong Axiom of Revealed Preference
C B is inconsistent with B C. D p I p I I I The data do not violate the WARP but ...
50
The Strong Axiom of Revealed Preference
The data do not violate the WARP but there are 3 violations of the SARP. I I I
51
The Strong Axiom of Revealed Preference
That the observed choice data satisfy the SARP is a condition necessary and sufficient for there to be a well-behaved preference relation that “rationalizes” the data. So our 3 data cannot be rationalized by a well-behaved preference relation.
52
Recovering Indifference Curves
Suppose we have the choice data satisfy the SARP. Then we can discover approximately where are the consumer’s indifference curves. How?
53
Recovering Indifference Curves
Suppose we observe: A: (p1,p2) = ($1,$1) & (x1,x2) = (15,15) B: (p1,p2) = ($2,$1) & (x1,x2) = (10,20) C: (p1,p2) = ($1,$2) & (x1,x2) = (20,10) D: (p1,p2) = ($2,$5) & (x1,x2) = (30,12) E: (p1,p2) = ($5,$2) & (x1,x2) = (12,30). Where lies the indifference curve containing the bundle A = (15,15)?
54
Recovering Indifference Curves
The table showing direct preference revelations is:
55
Recovering Indifference Curves
Direct revelations only; the WARP is not violated by the data.
56
Recovering Indifference Curves
Indirect preference revelations add no extra information, so the table showing both direct and indirect preference revelations is the same as the table showing only the direct preference revelations:
57
Recovering Indifference Curves
Both direct and indirect revelations; neither WARP nor SARP are violated by the data.
58
Recovering Indifference Curves
Since the choices satisfy the SARP, there is a well-behaved preference relation that “rationalizes” the choices.
59
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 A: (p1,p2)=(1,1); (x1,x2)=(15,15) B: (p1,p2)=(2,1); (x1,x2)=(10,20) C: (p1,p2)=(1,2); (x1,x2)=(20,10) D: (p1,p2)=(2,5); (x1,x2)=(30,12) E: (p1,p2)=(5,2); (x1,x2)=(12,30). E B D A C x1
60
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 A: (p1,p2)=(1,1); (x1,x2)=(15,15) B: (p1,p2)=(2,1); (x1,x2)=(10,20) C: (p1,p2)=(1,2); (x1,x2)=(20,10) D: (p1,p2)=(2,5); (x1,x2)=(30,12) E: (p1,p2)=(5,2); (x1,x2)=(12,30). E B D A C x1 Begin with bundles revealed to be less preferred than bundle A.
61
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 A: (p1,p2)=(1,1); (x1,x2)=(15,15). A x1
62
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 A: (p1,p2)=(1,1); (x1,x2)=(15,15). A x1
63
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 A: (p1,p2)=(1,1); (x1,x2)=(15,15). A is directly revealed preferred to any bundle in A x1
64
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 A: (p1,p2)=(1,1); (x1,x2)=(15,15) B: (p1,p2)=(2,1); (x1,x2)=(10,20). E B D A C x1
65
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 A: (p1,p2)=(1,1); (x1,x2)=(15,15) B: (p1,p2)=(2,1); (x1,x2)=(10,20). B A x1
66
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 A is directly revealed preferred to B and … B A x1
67
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 B is directly revealed preferred to all bundles in B x1
68
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 so, by transitivity, A is indirectly revealed preferred to all bundles in B x1
69
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 so A is now revealed preferred to all bundles in the union. B A x1
70
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 A: (p1,p2)=(1,1); (x1,x2)=(15,15) C: (p1,p2)=(1,2); (x1,x2)=(20,10). E B D A C x1
71
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 A: (p1,p2)=(1,1); (x1,x2)=(15,15) C: (p1,p2)=(1,2); (x1,x2)=(20,10). A C x1
72
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 A is directly revealed preferred to C and ... A C x1
73
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 C is directly revealed preferred to all bundles in C x1
74
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 so, by transitivity, A is indirectly revealed preferred to all bundles in C x1
75
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 so A is now revealed preferred to all bundles in the union. B A C x1
76
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 so A is now revealed preferred to all bundles in the union. Therefore the indifference curve containing A must lie everywhere else above this shaded set. B A C x1
77
Recovering Indifference Curves
Now, what about the bundles revealed as more preferred than A?
78
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 A: (p1,p2)=(1,1); (x1,x2)=(15,15) B: (p1,p2)=(2,1); (x1,x2)=(10,20) C: (p1,p2)=(1,2); (x1,x2)=(20,10) D: (p1,p2)=(2,5); (x1,x2)=(30,12) E: (p1,p2)=(5,2); (x1,x2)=(12,30). E B A D C A x1
79
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 A: (p1,p2)=(1,1); (x1,x2)=(15,15) D: (p1,p2)=(2,5); (x1,x2)=(30,12). A D x1
80
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 D is directly revealed preferred to A. A D x1
81
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 D is directly revealed preferred to A. Well-behaved preferences are convex A D x1
82
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 D is directly revealed preferred to A. Well-behaved preferences are convex so all bundles on the line between A and D are preferred to A also. A D x1
83
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 D is directly revealed preferred to A. Well-behaved preferences are convex so all bundles on the line between A and D are preferred to A also. A D As well, ... x1
84
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 all bundles containing the same amount of commodity 2 and more of commodity 1 than D are preferred to D and therefore are preferred to A also. A D x1
85
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 bundles revealed to be strictly preferred to A A D x1
86
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 A: (p1,p2)=(1,1); (x1,x2)=(15,15) B: (p1,p2)=(2,1); (x1,x2)=(10,20) C: (p1,p2)=(1,2); (x1,x2)=(20,10) D: (p1,p2)=(2,5); (x1,x2)=(30,12) E: (p1,p2)=(5,2); (x1,x2)=(12,30). E B A D C A x1
87
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 A: (p1,p2)=(1,1); (x1,x2)=(15,15) E: (p1,p2)=(5,2); (x1,x2)=(12,30). E A x1
88
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 E is directly revealed preferred to A. E A x1
89
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 E is directly revealed preferred to A. Well-behaved preferences are convex E A x1
90
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 E is directly revealed preferred to A. Well-behaved preferences are convex so all bundles on the line between A and E are preferred to A also. E A x1
91
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 E is directly revealed preferred to A. Well-behaved preferences are convex so all bundles on the line between A and E are preferred to A also. E A As well, ... x1
92
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 all bundles containing the same amount of commodity 1 and more of commodity 2 than E are preferred to E and therefore are preferred to A also. E A x1
93
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 More bundles revealed to be strictly preferred to A E A x1
94
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 Bundles revealed earlier as preferred to A E B A C D x1
95
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 All bundles revealed to be preferred to A E B A C D x1
96
Recovering Indifference Curves
Now we have upper and lower bounds on where the indifference curve containing bundle A may lie.
97
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 All bundles revealed to be preferred to A A x1 All bundles revealed to be less preferred to A
98
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 All bundles revealed to be preferred to A A x1 All bundles revealed to be less preferred to A
99
Recovering Indifference Curves
x2 The region in which the indifference curve containing bundle A must lie. A x1
100
Index Numbers Over time, many prices change. Are consumers better or worse off “overall” as a consequence? Index numbers give approximate answers to such questions.
101
Index Numbers Two basic types of indices price indices, and
quantity indices Each index compares expenditures in a base period and in a current period by taking the ratio of expenditures.
102
Quantity Index Numbers
A quantity index is a price-weighted average of quantities demanded; i.e. (p1,p2) can be base period prices (p1b,p2b) or current period prices (p1t,p2t).
103
Quantity Index Numbers
If (p1,p2) = (p1b,p2b) then we have the Laspeyres quantity index;
104
Quantity Index Numbers
If (p1,p2) = (p1t,p2t) then we have the Paasche quantity index;
105
Quantity Index Numbers
How can quantity indices be used to make statements about changes in welfare?
106
Quantity Index Numbers
If then so consumers overall were better off in the base period than they are now in the current period.
107
Quantity Index Numbers
If then so consumers overall are better off in the current period than in the base period.
108
Price Index Numbers A price index is a quantity-weighted average of prices; i.e. (x1,x2) can be the base period bundle (x1b,x2b) or else the current period bundle (x1t,x2t).
109
Price Index Numbers If (x1,x2) = (x1b,x2b) then we have the Laspeyres price index;
110
Price Index Numbers If (x1,x2) = (x1t,x2t) then we have the Paasche price index;
111
Price Index Numbers How can price indices be used to make statements about changes in welfare? Define the expenditure ratio
112
Price Index Numbers If then so consumers overall are better off in the current period.
113
Price Index Numbers But, if then so consumers overall were better off in the base period.
114
Full Indexation? Changes in price indices are sometimes used to adjust wage rates or transfer payments. This is called “indexation”. “Full indexation” occurs when the wages or payments are increased at the same rate as the price index being used to measure the aggregate inflation rate.
115
Full Indexation? Since prices do not all increase at the same rate, relative prices change along with the “general price level”. A common proposal is to index fully Social Security payments, with the intention of preserving for the elderly the “purchasing power” of these payments.
116
Full Indexation? The usual price index proposed for indexation is the Paasche quantity index (the Consumers’ Price Index). What will be the consequence?
117
Full Indexation? Notice that this index uses current period prices to weight both base and current period consumptions.
118
Full Indexation? x2 Base period budget constraint Base period choice
119
Full Indexation? x2 Base period budget constraint Base period choice
Current period budget constraint before indexation x1 x1b
120
Full Indexation? x2 Base period budget constraint Base period choice
Current period budget constraint after full indexation x2b x1 x1b
121
Full Indexation? x2 Base period budget constraint Base period choice
Current period budget constraint after indexation x2b Current period choice after indexation x1 x1b
122
Full Indexation? x2 Base period budget constraint Base period choice
Current period budget constraint after indexation x2b Current period choice after indexation x2t x1 x1b x1t
123
Full Indexation? x2 (x1t,x2t) is revealed preferred to (x1b,x2b) so full indexation makes the recipient strictly better off if relative prices change between the base and current periods. x2b x2t x1 x1b x1t
124
Full Indexation? So how large is this “bias” in the US CPI?
A table of recent estimates of the bias is given in the Journal of Economic Perspectives, Volume 10, No. 4, p. 160 (1996). Some of this list of point and interval estimates are as follows:
125
Full Indexation?
126
Full Indexation? So suppose a social security recipient gained by 1% per year for 20 years. Q: How large would the bias have become at the end of the period?
127
Full Indexation? So suppose a social security recipient gained by 1% per year for 20 years. Q: How large would the bias have become at the end of the period? A: so after 20 years social security payments would be about 22% “too large”.
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.