Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

IMPORT TARIFFS AND QUOTAS UNDER PERFECT COMPETITION

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "IMPORT TARIFFS AND QUOTAS UNDER PERFECT COMPETITION"— Presentation transcript:

1 IMPORT TARIFFS AND QUOTAS UNDER PERFECT COMPETITION
8 1 A Brief History of the World Trade Organization 2 The Gains from Trade 3 Import Tariffs for a Small Country 4 Import Tariffs for a Large Country 5 Import Quotas 6 Conclusions IMPORT TARIFFS AND QUOTAS UNDER PERFECT COMPETITION

2 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Introduction During the 2000 presidential campaign, President George W. Bush promised to consider implementing a tariff on the imports of steel. This was a political move to secure votes in large steel-producing states as the tariffs would “protect” the domestic producers of steel. The steel tariff is an example of a trade policy—a government action meant to influence the amount of international trade. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

3 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Introduction Because gains from trade are unevenly spread, producers often feel the government should help them limit losses due to competition from trade. Trade policy can include the use of import tariffs (taxes on imports), import quotas (limits on imports), and subsidies for exports. We will assume that firms are perfectly competitive. They produce a homogeneous good and are small compared to the market. Firms are price takers © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

4 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
The Gains from Trade We will now demonstrate the gains from trade using Home demand and supply curves, together with the concepts of consumer surplus and producer surplus. Consumer and Producer Surplus Figure 8.1 (a) shows the Home demand curve D where consumers face a price of P1. Remember, CS is the difference between the price the consumer is willing to pay and the actual price. Part (b) of figure 8.1 illustrates producer surplus. Remember that PS is the difference between MC and price, where the supply curve represents a firm’s MC. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

5 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
The Gains from Trade Figure 8.1 (a) Adding up all the individual surplus for each point on the demand curve gives us total consumer surplus—the area between the demand and the price paid—up to the quantity sold The demand curve gives us the consumer’s value for each unit of the good. Given P1, consumers will buy a total of D1. A consumer who purchases D2 has a value of P2, but only has to pay P1 – that gives surplus equal to (P2-P1) Price Total Consumer surplus, CS P2 Surplus for consumer purchasing quantity D2 P1 Figure 8.1 (a) Consumer and Producer Surplus In panel (a), the consumer surplus from purchasing quantity D1 at price P1 is the area below the demand curve and above that price. The consumer who purchases D2 is willing to pay price P2 but has to pay only P1. The difference is the consumer surplus and represents the satisfaction of consumers over and above the amount paid. D D D Quantity © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

6 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
The Gains from Trade Figure 8.1 (b) A producer who sells S0 has a MC of P0, but gets P1. That gives surplus equal to (P1-P0) The supply curve gives us the consumer’s value for each unit of the good. Given P1, producers will sell a total of S1. Adding up all the individual surpluses for each point on the supply curve gives us total producer surplus—the area between the supply and the price received—up to the quantity sold. Price Total Producer surplus, PS S P1 Figure 8.1 (b) Consumer and Producer Surplus In panel (b), the producer surplus from supplying the quantity S1 at the price P1 is the area above the supply curve and below that price. The supplier who supplies unit S0 has marginal costs of P0 but sells it for P1. The difference is the producer surplus and represents the return to fixed factors of production in the industry. Surplus for firm producing quantity S0 P0 S S Quantity © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

7 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
The Gains from Trade No trade equilibrium Again we consider the world of two countries, Home and Foreign, with producers and consumers. Total Home welfare can be measured by adding up consumer and producer surplus. We will compare the welfare in Home in no-trade and free-trade situations. Figure 8.2 Price No-trade equilibrium CS S A PA PS Figure 8.2 (a) The Gains from Free Trade at Home With Home demand of D and supply of S, the no-trade equilibrium is at point A, at the price PA producing Q0. With free trade, the world price is PW, so quantity demanded increases to D1 and quantity supplied falls to S1. Since quantity demanded exceeds quantity supplied, Home imports D1 − S1. Consumer surplus increases by the area (b + d), and producer surplus falls by area b. The gains from trade are measured by area d. D Q Quantity © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

8 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
The Gains from Trade Free Trade for a Small Country Suppose Home can now engage in trade. The world price PW is determined by the supply and demand in the world market (shown in in figure 8.2 (b)). Suppose Home is a small country. Price taker in the world market Faces a fixed price at PW Assume PW is below the Home no-trade price PA. At the lower price, Home will be an importer of the product at the world price. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

9 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
The Gains from Trade Figure 8.2 At lower world price, consumer surplus increases to a+b+d  an increase of b+d from no-trade (b) Free Trade Price S At lower world price, producer surplus falls to c  a decrease of b from no-trade a PA PW b Gain in trade is triangle d with area equal to ½(M1)(PA-PW) d Figure 8.2 (b) The Gains from Free Trade at Home With Home demand of D and supply of S, the no-trade equilibrium is at point A, at the price PA producing Q0. With free trade, the world price is PW, so quantity demanded increases to D1 and quantity supplied falls to S1. Since quantity demanded exceeds quantity supplied, Home imports D1 − S1. Consumer surplus increases by the area (b + d), and producer surplus falls by area b. The gains from trade are measured by area d. c D S D Quantity Imports, M1 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

10 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
The Gains from Trade Home Import Demand Curve We can derive the import demand curve, shown in figure 8.3 The relationship between the world price of a good and the quantity of imports demanded by Home consumers. At the no-trade equilibrium, there are zero imports This is shown as point A′ in panel (b). At the world price of PW, the quantity demanded is greater than quantity supplied, and we import M1. This is point B in panel (b). Joining A′ and B gives import demand curve M. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

11 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
The Gains from Trade Figure 8.3 (a) (b) No-trade equilibrium Each point on the import demand curve is a point that corresponds to Home imports at a given Home price Price Price S A' PA PW A B Figure 8.3 Home Import Demand With Home demand of D and supply of S, the no-trade equilibrium is at point A, with the price PA and import quantity Q0. Import demand at this price is zero, as shown by the point A‘ in panel (b). At a lower world price of PW, import demand is M1 = D1 − S1, as shown by point B. Joining up all points between A' and B, we obtain the import demand curve, M. Import demand curve, M D S Q D Quantity M Imports Imports, M1 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

12 Import Tariffs for a Small Country
Free Trade for a Small Country Since Home is a small country, the tariff does not affect world prices. The Foreign export supply curve X* is horizontal at the world price PW. Effect of the Tariff The new export supply curve shifts up to X*+t. Quantity demanded falls while quantity supplied rises However, as firms increase the quantity produced, the marginal costs of production rise. The domestic price will equal the import price. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

13 Import Tariffs for a Small Country
Figure 8.4 Home price rises by the amount of the tariff. Home supply increases and Home demand decreases  Imports fall to M2 No-trade equilibrium Price Price S A M2 C X*+t PW+t S D2 Figure 8.4 Tariff for a Small Country Applying a tariff of t dollars will increase the import price from PW to PW + t. The domestic price of that good also rises to PW + t. This price rise leads to an increase in Home supply from S1 to S2, and a decrease in Home demand from D1 to D2, in panel (a). Imports fall due to the tariff, from M1 to M2 in panel (b). As a result, the equilibrium shifts from point B to C. B Foreign export supply, X* PW D M S D1 Quantity M1 Imports M2 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

14 Import Tariffs for a Small Country
Effect of the Tariff on Consumer Surplus With the tariff, consumers now pay the higher price, PW+t, and their surplus is the area under the demand curve and above the higher price, PW+t. The fall in consumer surplus due to the tariff is the area in-between the two prices and to the left of Home demand, (a+b+c+d) in panel (a.1) of figure 8.5. This area is the amount that consumers lose due to the higher price caused by the tariff. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

15 Import Tariffs for a Small Country
Figure 8.5 (a.1) No-trade equilibrium Lost consumer surplus due to the higher price with the tariff is equal to the shaded area (a+b+c+d) Price S A a b d c PW+t PW Figure 8.5 (a) Effect of Tariff on Welfare The tariff increases the price from P W to P W + t. As a result, consumer surplus falls by (a + b + c + d). Producer surplus rises by area a, and government revenue increases by the area c. Therefore, the net loss in welfare, the deadweight loss to Home, is (b + d), which is measured by the two triangles b and d in panel (a). D S S D2 D Quantity M2 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

16 Import Tariffs for a Small Country
Effect of the Tariff on Producer Surplus With the tariff, producer surplus is the area above the supply and below the higher price, PW+t. Since the tariff increases Home price, firms can sell more goods, and producer surplus increases This area, a in figure 8.5 (a.2), is the amount that Home firms gain due to the higher price caused by the tariff. Increases in producer surplus can benefit Home workers but at the expense of consumers. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

17 Import Tariffs for a Small Country
Figure 8.5 (a.2) No-trade equilibrium The gain in producer surplus due to the higher price with the tariff is equal to the shaded area (a) Price S A b d PW+t PW a c Figure 8.5 (a) Effect of Tariff on Welfare The tariff increases the price from P W to P W + t. As a result, consumer surplus falls by (a + b + c + d). Producer surplus rises by area a, and government revenue increases by the area c. Therefore, the net loss in welfare, the deadweight loss to Home, is (b + d), which is measured by the two triangles b and d in panel (a). D S S D2 D Quantity M2 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

18 Import Tariffs for a Small Country
Effect of the Tariff on Government Revenue In addition to the tariff’s impact on consumers and producers, it also affects government revenue. The amount of revenue collected is the tariff t times the quantity of imports (D2 – S2). In figure 8.5 panel (a.3), the revenue is shown by area c. The collection of revenue is a gain for the government in the importing country. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

19 Import Tariffs for a Small Country
Figure 8.5 (a.3) The gain in government revenue due to the tariff is equal to the shaded area (c) This equals the tariff, t, times the quantity of imports, M2 No-trade equilibrium Price S A b d PW+t PW a c Figure 8.5 (a) Effect of Tariff on Welfare The tariff increases the price from P W to P W + t. As a result, consumer surplus falls by (a + b + c + d). Producer surplus rises by area a, and government revenue increases by the area c. Therefore, the net loss in welfare, the deadweight loss to Home, is (b + d), which is measured by the two triangles b and d in panel (a). D S S D2 D Quantity M2 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

20 Import Tariffs for a Small Country
Overall Effect of the Tariff on Welfare Note, we do not care whether the consumers facing higher prices are rich or poor, and do not care whether the specific factors in the industry earn a lot or a little. The overall impact of the tariff in the small country can be summarized as follows: Fall in consumer surplus -(a+b+c+d) Rise in producer surplus +a Rise in government revenue +c Net effect on Home welfare -(b+d) The areas b and d in figure 8.5 (a) correspond to the triangle (b+d) in figure 8.5 (b) and is the net welfare loss. We refer to this area as a deadweight loss—it is not offset by a gain elsewhere in the economy. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

21 Import Tariffs for a Small Country
Figure 8.5 (a) The deadweight loss is the loss to Home that is not offset by a corresponding gain No-trade equilibrium Price S a is a transfer from consumers to producers c is a transfer from consumers to government (b+d) is deadweight loss—losses not offset by other gains b = production distortion d = consumption distortion A b d PW+t PW a c Figure 8.5 (a) Effect of Tariff on Welfare The tariff increases the price from P W to P W + t. As a result, consumer surplus falls by (a + b + c + d). Producer surplus rises by area a, and government revenue increases by the area c. Therefore, the net loss in welfare, the deadweight loss to Home, is (b + d), which is measured by the two triangles b and d in panel (a). D S S D2 D Quantity M2 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

22 Import Tariffs for a Small Country
Figure 8.5 (b) M1 Imports X* M Price M2 X*+ t Dead weight loss due to tariff, b+d C Figure 8.5 (b) Effect of Tariff on Welfare The tariff increases the price from P W to P W + t. As a result, consumer surplus falls by (a + b + c + d). Producer surplus rises by area a, and government revenue increases by the area c. Therefore, the net loss in welfare, the deadweight loss to Home, is (b + d), which is measured by the single (combined) triangle b + d in panel (b). © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

23 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Why are Tariffs Used? Why do so many countries use tariffs if they always lead to deadweight losses? One idea is that developing countries do not have any other source of revenue. Import tariffs are “easy-to-collect” relative to income taxes. However, to the extent that developing countries recognize that tariffs have a higher deadweight loss, we would expect that over time they will shift away from such “easy-to-collect” taxes. A second reason is politics. The might government care more about producer surplus than consumer surplus. The benefits to producers (and their workers) are typically more concentrated on specific firms and states than the costs to consumers, which are spread nationwide. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

24 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
U.S. Tariffs on Steel We will estimate the deadweight loss due to the U.S. steel tariff in place from March 2002 to December 2003. President Bush requested that the U.S. International Trade Commission (ITC) initiate a Section 201 investigation into the steel industry. The tariffs varied across products, ranging from 10 to 20%—shown in Table 8.1—then falling over time to be eliminated after 3 years. 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

25 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
U.S. Tariffs on Steel President Bush took the recommendation of the ITC but applied even higher tariffs, ranging from 8% to 30%. Knowing the U.S. trading partners would be upset by this, President Bush exempted some countries from the tariffs. These included Canada, Mexico, Jordan, and Israel, which all have free trade agreements with the U.S., and 100 small developing countries that were exporting only a very small amount of steel to the U.S. 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

26 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
U.S. Tariffs on Steel Table 8.1 Table 8.1 U.S. ITC Recommended and Actual Tariffs for Steel Shown here are the tariffs recommended by the U.S. International Trade Commission for steel imports, and the actual tariffs that were applied in the first year. Source: Robert Read, 2005, “The Political Economy of Trade Protection: The Determinants and Welfare Impact of the 2002 U.S. Emergency Steel Safeguard Measures,” The World Economy, 1119–1137. 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

27 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
U.S. Tariffs on Steel Deadweight Loss due to the Steel Tariff We need to estimate the areas of triangle b+d we found in figure 8.5(b). The base is the change in imports, ΔM, and the height is the increase in domestic price, ΔP = t. Deadweight loss then equals DWL = ½ t ΔM. It is convenient to measure the deadweight loss relative to the value of imports, which is PW*M. We will also use the percentage tariff, t/PW, and the percentage change in the quantity of imports, % ΔM = ΔM/M. 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

28 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
U.S. Tariffs on Steel Figure 8.5 (b) Price We can measure DWL with the area of the triangle b+d from figure 8.5 (b) DWL = ½ t ΔM Deadweight loss due to the tariff, b+d PW+t t c Figure 8.5 (b) Effect of Tariff on Welfare The tariff increases the price from P W to P W + t. As a result, consumer surplus falls by (a + b + c + d). Producer surplus rises by area a, and government revenue increases by the area c. Therefore, the net loss in welfare, the deadweight loss to Home, is (b + d), which is measured by the single (combined) triangle b + d in panel (b). PW M M M Imports ΔM 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

29 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
U.S. Tariffs on Steel Using these definitions, the deadweight loss relative to the value of imports can be rewritten as: The most commonly used products had a tariff of 30%, so the percentage increase in the price is t/PW = 0.3, leading to %ΔM = 0.3. 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

30 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
U.S. Tariffs on Steel This leads to a DWL of The value of steel imports affected by the tariff was about $4.7 billion prior to March 2002 and $3.5 billion after March 2002. Average imports over the two years were $4.1 billion. The dollar magnitude of deadweight loss is equal to $185 million. 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

31 Import Tariffs for a Large Country
Under the small country assumption that we have used so far, the importing country is always harmed due to the tariff. The small country is a world price taker. If we consider a large enough importing country or a large country, however, then we might expect that its tariff will change the world price. Its imports are large enough that it can affect world price with a change in its imports. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

32 Import Tariffs for a Large Country
Foreign Export Supply If the Home country is large, then the Foreign export supply curve X* is no longer horizontal at the world price PW. We construct the Foreign export supply curve in a fashion similar to the import demand curve. In panel (a) of figure 8.6, we show the Foreign demand curve D* and supply curve S*, giving price of PA* at A*. At this point, Foreign exports are zero. Suppose the world price is PW above PA*. At the higher price, there is a Foreign excess supply of X1* = S1* - D1*, which will be exported at the price of PW at point B*. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

33 Import Tariffs for a Large Country
Figure 8.6 (a) Foreign Mkt (b) World Mkt World price increases to PW, increasing exports to X1* This gives us our Foreign export supply curve for the large country Price Price At the world price, PA*, exports are zero at A*’ Foreign export supply, X* D* S* B* X1* PW D1* S1* Figure 8.6 Foreign Export Supply In panel (a), with Foreign demand of D* and Foreign supply of S*, the no-trade equilibrium in Foreign is at point A*, with the price of PA*. At this price, the Foreign market is in equilibrium and Foreign exports are zero—point A* in panel (a) and point A*’ in panel (b), respectively. When the world price, PW, is higher than Foreign’s no-trade price, the quantity supplied by Foreign, S*1, exceeds the quantity demanded by Foreign, D*1, and Foreign exports X*1 = S*1 − D*1. In panel (b), joining up points A*' and B*, we obtain the upward-sloping export supply curve X*. With the Home import demand of M, the world equilibrium is at point B*, with the price PW. Home import demand, M A* A*' PA* Quantity Exports Foreign exports, X1* © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

34 Import Tariffs for a Large Country
Effect of the Tariff Figure 8.7 we show the effect when Home applies a tariff of t dollars on imports. Foreign export supply curve shifts up by exactly the amount of the tariff, shifting from X* to X*+t. The Home price rises by less than t, and the Foreign producers receive, P*, which is less than PW. The tariff drives a wedge between what Home consumers pay and what foreign producers receive, with the difference, t, going to the Home government. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

35 Import Tariffs for a Large Country
Figure 8.7 (without welfare effects) (a) Home market (b) Foreign market Price Price No-trade equilibrium X*+t S A t X* C P*+t t t PW B* Figure 8.7 Tariff for a Large Country The tariff shifts up the export supply curve from X* to X* + t. As a result, the Home price increases from PW to P* + t, and the Foreign price falls from PW to P*. The deadweight loss at Home is the area of the triangle (b + d), and Home also has a terms-of-trade gain of area e. Foreign loses the area (e + f), so the net loss in world welfare is the triangle (b + d + f). P* C* D M S1 S D2 D Quantity M2 M1 Imports M2 M1 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

36 Import Tariffs for a Large Country
Home Welfare Fall in consumer surplus -(a+b+c+d) Rise in producer surplus +a Rise in government revenue +(c + e) Net effect on Home welfare e – (b+d) + (e) The triangle (b+d) is the deadweight loss due to the tariff. Area e offsets part of the loss. If e > (b+d), then Home is better off. If e < (b+d), then Home is worse off. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

37 Import Tariffs for a Large Country
Figure 8.7 (with welfare effects) If the gain of e is greater than the loss of (b+d), Home gains (a) Home market (b) Foreign market No-trade equilibrium Price Price X*+t S b+d t X* A C Figure 8.7 Tariff for a Large Country The tariff shifts up the export supply curve from X* to X* + t. As a result, the Home price increases from PW to P* + t, and the Foreign price falls from PW to P*. The deadweight loss at Home is the area of the triangle (b + d), and Home also has a terms-of-trade gain of area e. P*+t PW P* a c b d B* e C* e D M S1 S D2 D Quantity M2 M1 Imports © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

38 Import Tariffs for a Large Country
Home welfare may improve, but it comes at the expense of foreign exporters. Foreign and World Welfare The Foreign loss, measured by (e+f) also in figure 8.7, is the loss in Foreign producer surplus from selling fewer goods to Home at a lower price. The area e is the terms-of-trade gain for Home (P*<PW) but an equivalent terms-of-trade loss for Foreign. Additionally, there is an extra deadweight loss in Foreign of f, giving a combined total greater than the benefits to Home. Therefore, it is sometimes called the “beggar thy neighbor” tariff. There is a world welfare loss = b + d + f © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

39 Import Tariffs for a Large Country
Figure 8.7 (with welfare effects) Foreign loses (e+f) as loss of Foreign producer surplus, from selling fewer goods at a lower price (a) Home market (b) Foreign market No-trade equilibrium Price Price X*+t S b+d t X* A C Figure 8.7 Tariff for a Large Country The tariff shifts up the export supply curve from X* to X* + t. As a result, the Home price increases from PW to P* + t, and the Foreign price falls from PW to P*. The deadweight loss at Home is the area of the triangle (b + d), and Home also has a terms-of-trade gain of area e. Foreign loses the area (e + f), so the net loss in world welfare is the triangle (b + d + f). P*+t PW P* a c b d B* e e f D C* M S1 S D2 D Quantity M2 M1 Imports © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

40 U.S. Tariffs on Steel Once Again
Optimal Tariff Compute the deadweight loss (area b+d) and the terms-of-trade gain (area e) for each imported steel product. Rather than do all these calculations, however, we can use the concept of the optimal tariff. The tariff that leads to the maximum increase in welfare for the importing country. We have shown that for a small tariff, a large country can gain. But if the tariff is too large, the country will still lose. Figure 8.8 graphs Home welfare against the level of the tariff. 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

41 U.S. Tariffs on Steel Once Again
The Optimal tariff maximizes the Importer’s welfare, Point C Figure 8.8 Too high of a tariff will decrease importer’s welfare and can increase to the point where there is no trade Terms of trade gain exceeds deadweight loss Importer’s Welfare C Terms of trade gain is less than deadweight loss B' Free Trade B Figure 8.8 Tariffs and Welfare for a Large Country For a large importing country, a tariff initially increases the importer’s welfare because the terms-of-trade gain exceeds the deadweight loss. So the importer’s welfare rises from point B. Welfare continues to rise until the tariff is at its optimal level (point C ). After that, welfare falls. If the tariff is too large (greater than at B' ), then welfare will fall below the free-trade level. For a prohibitive tariff, with no imports at all, the importer’s welfare will be at the no-trade level, at point A. A No Trade Optimal Tariff Prohibitive Tariff Tariff 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

42 U.S. Tariffs on Steel Once Again
Optimal Tariff Formula The optimal tariff depends on the elasticity of Foreign export supply, EX*. Optimal Tariff = 1/EX*. For a small importing country, the elasticity of Foreign export supply is infinite, and so the optimal tariff is zero. As the elasticity of Foreign export supply decreases, Foreign export supply curve is steeper, the optimal tariff is higher. 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

43 U.S. Tariffs on Steel Once Again
Optimal Tariffs for Steel If we apply this formula to the U.S. steel tariffs, we can see how the tariffs applied compare to the theoretical optimal tariff. Table 8.2 shows various steel products along with their respective elasticities of export supply to the U.S. We can compare the actual tariff to the optimal tariff to see where there were gains and where there were losses from the tariffs. But what about retaliation?... 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

44 U.S. Tariffs on Steel Once Again
Table 8.2 Table 8.2 Optimal Tariffs for Steel Products This table shows optimal tariffs for steel products, calculated with the elasticity formula. Source: Elasticities of export supply provided by Christian Broda and David Weinstein, 2006, “Globalization and the Gains from Variety,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, May, 121(2), 541–585. 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

45 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Import Quotas On January 1, 2005, China was poised to become the world’s largest exporter of textiles and apparel. On that date, the Multifibre Arrangement (MFA) was abolished. Under the MFA, import quotas restricted the amount of nearly every textile and apparel product that was imported to Canada, Europe, and the U.S. The quotas were to protect their own domestic firms producing those products. The threat of import competition from China led the U.S. and Europe to negotiate new quotas with China. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

46 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Import Quotas Import Quota in a Small Country Suppose the import quota of M2<M1 is imposed. This essentially gives us a vertical supply curve, X in panel b (at prices above PW). Fixes the import quantity at M2, price rises to P2. Qty supplied rises to S2 and qty demanded falls to D2. For every level of import quota, there is an equivalent import tariff Has the same price and quantity effects as the quota. The equivalent tariff is: t = P2 – PW © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

47 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Import Quotas Figure 8.9 (with quota) Consumers loses surplus of (a+b+c+d), producers gain (a). Welfare of Home depends on what happens to (c), the total quota rents. The new Export Supply curve crosses the Import Demand curve at a new price and quantity of imports At the new higher price P2, Home Supply increases to S2, Demand decreases to D2 and imports fall to M2 Always have a deadweight loss of (b+d) like the tariff With the Quota, the Foreign export supply becomes vertical at the quota quantity No-trade equilibrium S Price Price A c a d b+d b P2 C S2 D2 Foreign export supply, X* Figure 8.9 Quota for a Small Country Under free trade, the Foreign export supply curve is horizontal at the world price PW, and the free-trade equilibrium is at point B with imports of M1. Applying an import quota of M2 < M1 leads to the vertical export supply curve with the equilibrium at point C. The quota increases the import price from PW to P2. There would be the same impact on price and quantities if instead of the quota, a tariff of t = P2 − PW had been used. B PW M2 Home import demand, M D S1 D1 Quantity M1 Imports (a) Home market (b) Import market © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

48 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Import Quotas There are four possible ways these rents can be allocated. Giving the Quota to Home Firms: Quota licenses can be given to Home firms Permits to import the quantity allowed under the quota system. The net effects on Home welfare due to the quota are then as follows: Fall in consumer surplus -(a+b+c+d) Rise in producer surplus +a Quota rents earned at Home +c Net effect on Home welfare: -(b+d) This is the same loss we saw with a tariff. (b+d) is still a deadweight loss associated with the quota. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

49 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Import Quotas Rent Seeking Because of the gains associated with owning a quota license, firms have an incentive to engage in inefficient activities in order to obtain them. How licenses are allocated matters. If licenses are allocated in proportion to each firm’s production, Home firms will likely produce more than they can sell just to obtain the import licenses for the following year. Firms might engage in bribery or other lobbying activities to obtain the licenses. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

50 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Import Quotas Some suggest that the waste of resources devoted to rent seeking could be as large as the value of the rents themselves, c. If rent seeking occurs, welfare loss of quota is: Fall in consumer surplus -(a+b+c+d) Rise in producer surplus +a Net effect on Home welfare: -(b+c+d) This loss is larger than a tariff. It is thought rent seeking is worse in developing countries. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

51 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Import Quotas Auctioning the Quota The government of the importing country to auction off the quota licenses. In a well-organized, competitive auction, the revenue collected should exactly equal the value of the rents. Fall in consumer surplus -(a+b+c+d) Rise in producer surplus +a Auction revenue earned at Home +c Net effect on Home welfare: -(b+d) This is the same loss as the tariff. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

52 Auctioning Import Quotas in Australia and New Zealand
During the 1980s, Australia and New Zealand both auctioned the quota licenses to import specific goods. Table 8.3 shows the value of imports covered by quotas curing 1981–1987. In 1988, New Zealand announced plans to phase out import quotas as part of a liberalization of trade, and all quota licenses were eliminated by 1992. 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

53 Auctioning Import Quotas in Australia and New Zealand
Table 8.3 also shows the value of bids for the quota licenses. These are estimates of rents. If we take the ratio of the value of bids to the value of imports covered by the quota, we obtain an estimate of the tariff equivalent to the quota. These are shown in the final column of table 8.3 Since there was no penalty from not following through, some firms decided not to purchase the licenses after all. 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

54 Auctioning Import Quotas in Australia and New Zealand
Table 8.3 Table 8.3 Auction of Import Quotas in New Zealand Shown here are the value of imports, bids for import quota licenses, and the equivalent tariff values in New Zealand during years when its quota licenses were auctioned. Source: C. Fred Bergsten, Kimberly Ann Elliott, Jeffrey J. Schott, and Wendy E. Takacs, 1987, Auction Quotas and United States Trade Policy, Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington, D.C., 101. 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

55 Auctioning Import Quotas in Australia and New Zealand
The government therefore did not collect all the winning bids as revenue. For those that did buy their licenses, they could be resold and some were at much higher prices. This makes it appear that the government was not collecting all of the rents in area c. 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

56 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Import Quotas “Voluntary” Export Restraint The importing country can give authority for implementing the quota to the exporting government. This is often called a “voluntary” export restraint (VER) or a “voluntary” restraint agreement (VRA). In the 1980s the U.S. used this type of arrangement to restrict imports of Japanese automobiles. The Japanese government told each Japanese firm how much it could export to the U.S. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

57 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Import Quotas With VERs, quota rents are earned by foreign producers, making Home welfare: Fall in consumer surplus -(a+b+c+d) Rise in producer surplus +a Net effect on Home welfare: -(b+c+d) This is a higher net loss than with a tariff. Why would an importing country do this? It is typically political—the exporting country is less likely to retaliate since they gain the area c. This can often avoid a tariff or quota war. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

58 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Import Quotas Costs of Import Quotas in the U.S. Table 8.4 presents some estimates of Home deadweight losses and quota rents for some major U.S. quotas in the 1980’s. In all cases except Dairy, the rents were earned by Foreign exporters. Adding up the costs in the table, the total U.S. deadweight loss due to these quotas ranged from $8–$12 billion annually. Quota rents transferred another $7–$17 billion to foreigners. Some, but not all, of these costs are relevant today since many of the quotas are no longer in place. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

59 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Import Quotas Table 8.4 Table 8.4 Annual Cost of U.S. Import Protection ($ billions) Shown here are estimates of the deadweight losses and quota rents due to U.S. import quotas in the 1980s, for the years around Many of these quotas are no longer in place today. Source: Robert Feenstra, “How Costly Is Protectionism?” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Summer 1992, 159–178. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

60 China and the Multifibre Arrangement
One of the principles of GATT was that countries should not use quotas to restrict imports. The MFA was a major exception to that which allowed the industrialized countries to restrict imports of textile and apparel products from the developing countries. Organized under GATT, importing countries could join the MFA and arrange quotas bilaterally or unilaterally. Under the Uruguay round of WTO, developing countries were able to negotiate an end to this system of import quotas. Some developing countries and large producers in importing countries were concerned with the potential of Chinese exports on their economies. 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

61 China and the Multifibre Arrangement
Growth in Exports from China Immediately after January 1, 2005, exports of textiles and apparel from China grew rapidly. In 2005, China’s textile and apparel imports to the U.S. rose by more than 40% compared to 2004. Figure 8.10 (a) shows the change in the value of exports of textiles and apparel from different countries. Note China. The increases from China came at the expense of some higher-cost exporters, some of whose exports to the U.S. declined by 10 to 20%. 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

62 China and the Multifibre Arrangement
Figure 8.10 Figure 8.10 (a) Changes in Clothing and Textiles Exports to the United States after the MFA, 2004–2005 After the expiration of the Multifibre Arrangement (MFA), the value of clothing and textiles exports from China rose dramatically, as shown in panel (a). This reflects the surge in the quantity of exports that were formerly constrained under the MFA as well as a shift to Chinese exports from other, higher-cost producers such as Hong Kong, Taiwan, and South Korea. Source: James Harrigan and Geoffrey Barrows, 2006, “Testing the Theory of Trade Policy: Evidence from the Abrupt End of the Multifibre Arrangement,” NBER Working Paper No , October. 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

63 China and the Multifibre Arrangement
Panel (b) of figure 8.10 shows the percentage change in the prices of textiles and apparel products from each country, depending on whether the products were subject to the MFA quota before January 1, 2005, or not. China had the largest drop in the prices from 2004 to 2005. Many other countries had a substantial fall in their prices due to the end of the MFA quota. 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

64 China and the Multifibre Arrangement
Figure 8.10 Figure 8.10 (b) Changes in Clothing and Textiles Exports to the United States after the MFA, 2004–2005 After the expiration of the Multifibre Arrangement (MFA), the value of clothing and textiles exports from China rose dramatically. This reflects the surge in the quantity of exports that were formerly constrained under the MFA as well as a shift to Chinese exports from other, higher-cost producers such as Hong Kong, Taiwan, and South Korea. In panel (b), we see that the prices of goods constrained by the MFA typically fell by more than the average change in export prices after the MFA’s expiry. This is exactly what our theory of quotas predicts: the removal of quotas lowers import prices for consumers. Source: James Harrigan and Geoffrey Barrows, 2006, “Testing the Theory of Trade Policy: Evidence from the Abrupt End of the Multifibre Arrangement,” NBER Working Paper No , October. 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

65 China and the Multifibre Arrangement
Welfare Cost of the MFA Given the drop in prices in 2005, it is possible to estimate the welfare loss due to the MFA. Using the price drops from figure 8.10, the welfare loss for the U.S. (b+c+d), is estimated at $6.5 to $16.2 billion in 2005 from the MFA. Averaging out all losses and dividing among households gives an estimate of $100 per household, or 7% of total annual spending on apparel. 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

66 China and the Multifibre Arrangement
Import Quality Quotas are set on the quantity, not the quality of items imported. Selling a higher value good for the same quantity will still meet the quota limit but will bring more money back home. Incentive to export higher quality products. Prices dropped the most for the lower- priced items. An inexpensive T-shirt had a greater drop in price than a more expensively priced item. U.S. demand shifted towards the lower-priced items imported from China: there was “quality downgrading” in the exports from China. When a quota like the MFA is applied, there is an effect on quality. 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor


Download ppt "IMPORT TARIFFS AND QUOTAS UNDER PERFECT COMPETITION"

Similar presentations


Ads by Google