Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

ECO 301: INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "ECO 301: INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS"— Presentation transcript:

1 ECO 301: INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS
Kwabena Nkansah Darfor UCC

2 OVERVIEW OF CONSUMER BEHAVIOUR THEORY

3 Consumer Preferences and the Concept of Utility

4 Overview 2. Consumer Preferences and the Concept of Utility
1. Motivation 2. Consumer Preferences and the Concept of Utility 3. The Utility Function Marginal Utility and Diminishing Marginal Utility 4. Indifference Curves 5. The Marginal Rate of Substitution Some Special Functional Forms

5 Motivation • Why study consumer choice? Study of how consumers with limited resources choose goods and services Helps derive the demand curve for any good or service Businesses care about consumer demand curves Government can use this to determine how to help and whom to help buy certain goods and services

6 Consumer Preferences Consumer Preferences tell us how the consumer would rank (that is, compare the desirability of) any two combinations or allotments of goods, assuming these allotments were available to the consumer at no cost. These allotments of goods are referred to as baskets or bundles. These baskets are assumed to be available for consumption at a particular time, place and under particular physical circumstances.

7 Consumer Preferences Assumptions Complete and Transitive
Preferences are complete if the consumer can rank any two baskets of goods (A preferred to B; B preferred to A; or indifferent between A and B) Preferences are transitive if a consumer who prefers basket A to basket B, and basket B to basket C also prefers basket A to basket C A  B; B  C = > A  C

8 Consumer Preferences Assumptions Monotonic / Free Disposal
Preferences are monotonic if a basket with more of at least one good and no less of any good is preferred to the original basket.

9 Types of Ranking Example:
Students take an exam. After the exam, the students are ranked according to their performance. An ordinal ranking lists the students in order of their performance (i.e., Kweku did best, Kojo did second best, Akua did third best, and so on). A cardinal ranking gives the mark of the exam, based on an absolute marking standard (i.e., Kweku got 80, Kojo got 75, Akua got 74 and so on). Alternatively, if the exam were graded on a curve, the marks would be an ordinal ranking.

10 The Utility Function The three assumptions about preferences allow us to represent preferences with a utility function. Utility function – a function that measures the level of satisfaction a consumer receives from any basket of goods and services. – assigns a number to each basket so that more preferred baskets get a higher number than less preferred baskets. U = u(y)

11 The Utility Function Implications:
An ordinal concept: the precise magnitude of the number that the function assigns has no significance. Utility not comparable across individuals. Any transformation of a utility function that preserves the original ranking of bundles is an equally good representation of preferences. e.g. U = vs. U = + 2 represent the same preferences. Check that underlying preferences are complete, transitive, monotonic and averages are preferred to extremes.

12 Marginal Utility Marginal Utility of a good y
additional utility that the consumer gets from consuming a little more of y i.e. the rate at which total utility changes as the level of consumption of good y rises MUy = U/y slope of the utility function with respect to y See Figure 3.2

13 Diminishing Marginal Utility
The principle of diminishing marginal utility states that the marginal utility falls as the consumer consumes more of a good. See Figure 3.2

14 Diminishing Marginal Utility
See Figure 3.2

15 Marginal Utility The marginal utility of a good, x, is the additional utility that the consumer gets from consuming a little more of x when the consumption of all the other goods in the consumer’s basket remain constant. U(x, y) = x + y U/x (y held constant) = MUx U/y (x held constant) = MUy

16 Marginal Utility Example of U(H) and MUH U(H) = 10H – H2 MUH = 10 – 2H
4 16 6 24 36 -2 8 64 -6 10 100 -10

17 Marginal Utility U(H) = 10H – H2 MUH = 10 – 2H

18 Marginal Utility Example of U(H) and MUH
The point at which he should stop consuming homefood is the point at which MUH = 0 This gives H = 5. That is the point where Total Utility is flat. You can see that the utility is diminishing.

19 Marginal Utility – multiple goods
U = xy2 MUx = y2 MUy = 2xy More is better? More y more and more x indicates more U so yes it is monotonic Diminishing marginal utility? MU of x is not dependent of x. So the marginal utility of x (movies) does not decrease as the number of movies increases. MU of y increases with increase in number of operas (y) so neither exhibits diminishing returns.

20 Indifference Curves An Indifference Curve or Indifference Set: is the set of all baskets for which the consumer is indifferent An Indifference Map : Illustrates a set of indifference curves for a consumer

21 Indifference Curves Key Properties
1) Monotonicity => indifference curves have negative slope – and indifference curves are not “thick” 2) Transitivity => indifference curves do not cross 3) Completeness => each basket lies on only one indifference curve

22 Indifference Curves Monotonicity

23 Indifference Curves Cannot Cross Suppose that B preferred to A.
but..by definition of IC, B indifferent to C A indifferent to C => B indifferent to C by transitivity. And thus a contradiction.

24 Indifference Curves U = xy2 Example x y xy^2 8 4.24 143.8 4 6 144 3
Check that underlying preferences are complete, transitive, and monotonic. x y xy^2 8 4.24 143.8 4 6 144 3 6.93 144.07 1 12 We show later that the diminishing MRS implies averages are preferred to extremes for indifference curves.

25 Indifference Curves Example: Utility and the single indifference curve.

26 Marginal Rate of Substitution
The marginal rate of substitution: is the maximum rate at which the consumer would be willing to substitute a little more of good x for a little less of good y; It is the increase in good x that the consumer would require in exchange for a small decrease in good y in order to leave the consumer just indifferent between consuming the old basket or the new basket; It is the rate of exchange between goods x and y that does not affect the consumer’s welfare; It is the negative of the slope of the indifference curve: MRSx,y = -y/x (for a constant level of preference)

27 Marginal Rate of Substitution
The Diminishing Marginal Rate of Substitution If the more of good x you have, the more you are willing to give up to get a little of good y or  the indifference curves get flatter as we move out along the horizontal axis and steeper as we move up along the vertical axis

28 Marginal Rate of Substitution
-y/x = MUx(x) + MUy(y) = 0 …along an IC… MUx/MUy = MRSx,y Positive marginal utility implies the indifference curve has a negative slope (implies monotonicity) Diminishing marginal utility implies the indifference curves are convex to the origin (implies averages preferred to extremes)

29 Marginal Rate of Substitution
The Marginal Rate of Substitution Implications of this substitution: Indifference curves are negatively-sloped, bowed out from the origin, preference direction is up and right Indifference curves do not intersect the axes

30 Indifference Curves Key Property
Averages preferred to extremes => indifference curves are bowed toward the origin (convex to the origin).

31 Indifference Curves Do the indifference curves intersect the axes?
A value of x = 0 or y = 0 is inconsistent with any positive level of utility.

32 Marginal Rate of Substitution
The Marginal Rate of Substitution Example: U = Ax2+By2; MUx=2Ax; MUy=2By (where: A and B positive) MRSx,y = MUx/MUy = 2Ax/2By = Ax/By Marginal utilities are positive (for positive x and y) Marginal utility of x increases in x; Marginal utility of y increases in y

33 Indifference Curves A. Is more better for both goods? Yes, since
 Example: U= (xy).5;MUx=y.5/2x.5; MUy=x.5/2y.5 A. Is more better for both goods? Yes, since marginal utilities are positive for both. B. Are the marginal utility for x and y diminishing? Yes. (For example, as x increases, for y constant, MUx falls.) C. What is the marginal rate of substitution of x for y? MRSx,y = MUx/MUy = y/x

34 Indifference Curves y Preference direction IC2 IC1 x
Example: Graphing Indifference Curves IC1 IC2 x y Preference direction

35 Special Functional Forms
Cobb-Douglas: U = Axy where:  +  = 1; A, , positive constants MUX = Ax-1y MUY =  Ax y-1 MRSx,y = (y)/(x) “Standard” case

36 Special Functional Forms
Example: Cobb-Douglas (speed vs. maneuverability) IC1 IC2 x y Preference Direction

37 Special Functional Forms
Perfect Substitutes: U = Ax + By Where: A, B positive constants MUx = A MUy = B MRSx,y = A/B so that 1 unit of x is equal to B/A units of y everywhere (constant MRS).

38 Special Functional Forms
Example: Perfect Substitutes (Tylenol, Extra-Strength Tylenol) x y IC1 IC2 IC3 Slope = -A/B

39 Numerical Example: Perfect Substitutes
Example 1: You have to decide whether to buy Goil gas or Mobil gas. You have $30. The price of Goil gas is $3 and the price of Mobil gas is $3.25. Since the goods are identical you will only buy gas at the lowest price. Therefore, you will buy 10 gallons of Goil gas. Note that if the goods are perfect substitutes you do not necessarily buy the good with the lowest price. If you get enough extra utility from the more expensive good, you may end up buying that good.

40 Special Functional Forms
Perfect Complements: U = Amin(x,y) where: A is a positive constant. MUx = 0 or A MUy = 0 or A MRSx,y is 0 or infinite or undefined (corner)

41 Special Functional Forms
Example: Perfect Complements (nuts and bolts) x y IC1 IC2

42 Numerical Example: Perfect Complements
Example 2: Each time you go to the movies you buy 2 bags of popcorn. The price of popcorn is $2.50 and the price of a movie ticket is $10. You have $30. Utility function: U(M,C) = Min (2M,C) Consumption ratio: C = 2M Budget constraint: 10M C = 30 Plug C = 2M into the budget constraint: 10M + 5M = 30 M = 2 C = 4

43 Special Functional Forms
Quasi-Linear Preferences: U = v(x) + Ay Where: A is a positive constant. MUx = v’(x) = V(x)/x, where  small MUy = A "The only thing that determines your personal trade-off between x and y is how much x you already have." *can be used to "add up" utilities across individuals*

44 • Special Functional Forms y IC2 IC1 IC’s have same slopes on any
Example: Quasi-linear Preferences (consumption of beverages) x y IC2 IC1 IC’s have same slopes on any vertical line

45 CONSUMER CHOICE

46 Key Definitions Budget Set: The set of baskets that are affordable
Budget Constraint: The set of baskets that the consumer may purchase given the limits of the available income. Budget Line: The set of baskets that one can purchase when spending all available income.

47 The Budget Constraint PXX + PYY ≤ I
Assume only two goods available: X and Y Price of x: Px ; Price of y: Py Income: I Total expenditure on basket (X,Y): PxX + PyY The Basket is Affordable if total expenditure does not exceed total Income: PXX + PYY ≤ I

48 A Budget Constraint Example
Two goods available: X and Y I = $10 Px = $1 Py = $2 All income spent on X → I/Px units of X bought All income spent on Y → I/Py units of X bought Budget Line 1: 1X + 2Y = 10 Or Y = 5 – X/2 Slope of Budget Line = -Px/Py = -1/2

49 • B A Budget Constraint Example I/PX = 10 Y X A C I/PY= 5
Budget line = BL1 -PX/PY = -1/2

50 Budget Constraint Location of budget line shows what the income level is. Increase in Income will shift the budget line to the right. More of each product becomes affordable Decrease in Income will shift the budget line to the left. less of each product becomes affordable

51 A Budget Constraint Example
Y X 10 5 BL1 6 12 BL2 I = $12 PX = $1 PY = $2 Y = 6 - X/2 …. BL2 If income rises, the budget line shifts parallel to the right (shifts out) If income falls, the budget line shifts parallel to the left (shifts in) Shift of a budget line

52 Budget Constraint Location of budget line shows what the income level is. Increase in Income will shift the budget line to the right. More of each product becomes affordable Decrease in Income will shift the budget line to the left. less of each product becomes affordable

53 A Budget Constraint Example
Y X 5 6 I = $10 PX = $1 PY = $3 Y = X/3 …. BL2 BL1 BL2 3.33 10 If the price of X rises, the budget line gets steeper and the horizontal intercept shifts in If the price of X falls, the budget line gets flatter and the horizontal intercept shifts out Rotation of a budget line

54 A Budget Constraint Example
Two goods available: X and Y I = $800 Px = $20 Py = $40 Budget Line 1: 20X + 40Y = 800 Or Y = 20 – X/2 Slope of Budget Line = -Px/Py = -1/2 All income spent on X → I/Px units of X bought All income spent on Y → I/Py units of X bought

55 A Budget Constraint Example

56 Consumer Choice Assume:  Only non-negative quantities
 "Rational” choice: The consumer chooses the basket that maximizes his satisfaction given the constraint that his budget imposes. Consumer’s Problem: Max U(X,Y) Subject to: PxX + PyY < I

57 Interior Optimum MRSx,y = MUx/MUy = Px/Py
Interior Optimum: The optimal consumption basket is at a point where the indifference curve is just tangent to the budget line. A tangent: to a function is a straight line that has the same slope as the function…therefore…. MRSx,y = MUx/MUy = Px/Py “The rate at which the consumer would be willing to exchange X for Y is the same as the rate at which they are exchanged in the marketplace.”

58 • Interior Consumer Optimum Y B Preference Direction
X Optimal Choice (interior solution) IC BL C B Preference Direction

59 Interior Consumer Optimum

60 Interior Consumer Optimum
Assumptions U (X,Y) = XY and MUx = Y while MUy = X I = $1,000 P = $50 and P = $200 Basket A contains (X=4, Y=4) Basket B contains (X=10, Y=2.5) Question: Is either basket the optimal choice for the consumer? X Y Basket A: MRSx,y = MUx/MUy = Y/X = 4/4 = 1 Slope of budget line = -Px/Py = -1/4 Basket B: MRSx,y = MUx/MUy = Y/X = 1/4

61 Interior Consumer Optimum
Y X U = 25 2.5 10 50X + 200Y = I Example

62 Equal Slope Condition MUx/Px = MUy/Py
“At the optimal basket, each good gives equal bang for the buck” Now, we have two equations to solve for two unknowns (quantities of X and Y in the optimal basket): 1. MUx/Px = MUY/PY 2. PxX + PyY = I

63 Constrained Optimization
What are the equations that the optimal consumption basket must fulfill if we want to represent the consumer’s choice among three goods? MU / P = MU / P is an example of “marginal reasoning” to maximize P X + P Y = I reflects the “constraint” X Y

64 Constrained Optimization
U(F,C) = FC PF = $1/unit PC = $2/unit I = $12 Solve for optimal choice of food and clothing

65 The Theory of Demand

66 Overview Individual Demand Curves
Income and Substitution Effects & the Slope of Demand Applications: The Work-Leisure Trade-off Consumer Surplus Constructing Market Demand The Effects of a Change in Price Optimal Choice Demand Curve

67 Individual Demand Curves
The Price Consumption Curve of Good X: Is the set of optimal baskets for every possible price of good x, holding all other prices and income constant.

68 • Price Consumption Curves Y (units) X (units) PX = 4 PX = 2 PX = 1
PX = 4 PX = 2 PX = 1 XA=2 XB=10 XC=16 10 PY = $4 I = $40 Price Consumption Curve 20 The price consumption curve for good x can be written as the quantity consumed of good x for any price of x. This is the individual’s demand curve for good x.

69 • Individual Demand Curve PX Individual Demand Curve For X PX = 4
XA XB XC Individual Demand Curve For X PX = 4 PX = 2 PX = 1 U increasing

70 Individual Demand Curve
Key Points The consumer is maximizing utility at every point along the demand curve The marginal rate of substitution falls along the demand curve as the price of x falls (if there was an interior solution). As the price of x falls, it causes the consumer to move down and to the right along the demand curve as utility increases in that direction. The demand curve is also the “willingness to pay” curve – and willingness to pay for an additional unit of X falls as more X is consumed.

71 Demand Curve for “X” Algebraically, we can solve for the individual’s demand using the following equations: 1. pxx + pyy = I 2. MUx/px = MUy/py – at a tangency. (If this never holds, a corner point may be substituted where x = 0 or y = 0)

72 Demand Curve with an Interior Solution
Suppose that U(x,y) = xy. MUx = y and MUy = x. The prices of x and y are px and py, respectively and income = I. We Have: 1. pxx + pyy = I 2. x/py = y/px Substituting the second condition into the budget constraint, we then have: 3. pxx + py(px/py)x = I or…x = I/2px

73 Change in Income & Demand
Income Consumption Curve The income consumption curve of good x is the set of optimal baskets for every possible level of income. We can graph the points on the income consumption curve as points on a shifting demand curve.

74 Income Consumption Curve

75 Engel Curves The income consumption curve for good x also can be written as the quantity consumed of good x for any income level. This is the individual’s Engel Curve for good x. When the income consumption curve is positively sloped, the slope of the Engel Curve is positive.

76 Engel Curves I ($) Engel Curve “X is a normal good” 92 68 40 X (units)
X (units) 92 68 40 Engel Curve I ($) “X is a normal good”

77 Definitions of Goods • If the income consumption curve shows that the consumer purchases more of good x as her income rises, good x is a normal good. • Equivalently, if the slope of the Engel curve is positive, the good is a normal good. • If the income consumption curve shows that the consumer purchases less of good x as her income rises, good x is an inferior good. • Equivalently, if the slope of the Engel curve is negative, the good is an inferior good.

78 Definitions of Goods Example: Backward Bending Engel Curve – a good can be normal over some ranges and inferior over others

79 Impact of Change in the Price of a Good
Substitution Effect: Relative change in price affects the amount of good that is bought as consumer tries to achieve the same level of utility Income Effect: Consumer’s purchasing power changes and affects the consumer in a way similar to effect of a change in income

80 The Substitution Effect
As the price of x falls, all else constant, good x becomes cheaper relative to good y. This change in relative prices alone causes the consumer to adjust his/ her consumption basket. This effect is called the substitution effect. The substitution effect always is negative. Usually, a move along a demand curve will be composed of both effects.

81 Impact of Change in the Price of a Good
Definition: As the price of x falls, all else constant, purchasing power rises. As the price of x rises, all else constant, purchasing power falls. This is called the income effect of a change in price. The income effect may be positive (normal good) or negative (inferior good).

82 Impact of Change in the Price of a Good
If price of a good falls – consumer substitutes into the good to achieve the same level of utility When price falls – purchasing power increases the consumer can buy the same amount and still have money left

83 The Substitution and Income Effects
Clothing Y X Food A C B XA XC XB BL1 BL2 BLd U1 U2 Initial Basket Final Basket Decomposition Basket

84 The Substitution and Income Effects

85 The Substitution and Income Effects
Initial Basket A Final Basket C Decomposition Basket B Clothing Y X Food A C B XA XC XB BL1 BL2 BLd U1 U2

86 The Substitution and Income Effects

87 Giffen Goods If a good is so inferior that the net effect of a price decrease of good x, all else constant, is a decrease in consumption of good x, good x is a Giffen good. For Giffen goods, demand does not slope down. When might an income effect be large enough to offset the substitution effect? The good would have to represent a very large proportion of the budget.

88 Giffen Goods – Income and Substitution Effects

89 Example: Example – Income and Substitution Effects
Suppose U(x,y) = xy  MUx = y, MUy = x Py = $1/unit and I = $72 Suppose that Px1 = $9/unit. What is the (initial) optimal consumption basket? Tangency Condition: MUx/MUy = Px/Py  y = 9x Constraint: Pxx + Pyy = I  9x + y = 72 Solving: x = 4 and y = 36

90 Example: Example – Income and Substitution Effects
Suppose U(x,y) = XY  MUx = y, MUy = x Py = $1/unit and I = $72 Suppose that price of x falls and Px2 = $4/unit. What is the (final) optimal consumption basket? Tangency Condition: MUx/MUy = Px/Py  y = 4x Constraint: Pxx + Pyy = I  4x + y = 72 Solving: x = 9 and y = 36

91 Example – Income and Substitution Effects
Find the decomposition basket B. It must lie on the original indifference curve U1 along with basket A  U1 = XY = 4(36) = 144. It must lie at the point where the decomposition budget line is tangent to the indifference curve. Price of X (PX) on the decomposition budget line is final price of $4. Tangency Condition: MUx/MUy = Px/Py  y = 4x Combined with XY = 144  x = 6, y = 24 Substitution Effect: 6 – 4 = 2 units of X Income Effect: 9 – 6 = 3 units of X

92 Consumer Surplus The individual’s demand curve can be seen as the individual’s willingness to pay curve. On the other hand, the individual must only actually pay the market price for (all) the units consumed. Consumer Surplus is the difference between what the consumer is willing to pay and what the consumer actually pays.

93 Consumer Surplus Definition: The net economic benefit to the consumer due to a purchase (i.e. the willingness to pay of the consumer net of the actual expenditure on the good) is called consumer surplus. The area under an ordinary demand curve and above the market price provides a measure of consumer surplus

94 Consumer Surplus G = .5(10-3)(28) = 98 H+I= 28 +2 = 30
CS2 = .5(10-2)(32) = 128 CSP = (10-P)(40-4P)

95 Market Demand The market demand function is the horizontal sum of the individual (or segment) demands. In other words, market demand is obtained by adding the quantities demanded by the individuals (or segments) at each price and plotting this total quantity for all possible prices.

96 Market Demand Q = 10 - P Segment 1 Q = 20 – 5P Segment 2 Market demand
4 10 Q P


Download ppt "ECO 301: INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS"

Similar presentations


Ads by Google