Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published byTy Chesnut Modified over 9 years ago
1
Agenda Medicare Dialysis Model
2
Medicare Established 1965 –President Johnson Who’s covered? –65+ and legal and paid Medicare taxes for +10 years –Social Security disability for +2 years –Social Security disability and ALS –On dialysis or need kidney transplant Part A –Hospital stays +1 night –Skilled nursing facilities (short term) Part B: –Most medical care Part C: Medicare Advantage –Established 1997. Complicated –22% of Medicare population –A+B through private providers Part D: –Established 2003. Complicated –Private plans that cover drugs
3
Medicare Insurance Premium: $96.40/mo. for Part B –Higher for higher incomes Deductibles –$1069 for hospital stays (Part A) –$135 for Part B Co-Pays for Part B –20% for most –0% for lab work Out of pocket expenses can be covered by –Medicaid for poor –Private insurance (Medigap) –Except “donut hole” for drug coverage
5
for Part Afor Parts B & D
8
Medicare Reimbursement Fee for service Sets rates –Lower than private health insurance –Sometimes using Average Sales Price (ASP) –Does not negotiate drug prices for Part D Moving towards “pay for performance” –Paper looks at optimal contract for dialysis
9
Agenda Medicare Dialysis Model
10
Renal = kidney related Produce urine Remove toxins from blood Homeostasis = regulate –Electrolytes (salts) –pH –Produces renin regulating blood pressure –Absorbs glucose and amio acids –Metabolizes vitamin D into calcitrol (calcium balance) –Erythropoietin (EPO) production (hormone for red blood cell production) Kidneys
11
Kidney Function estimated glomerular filtration rate (eGFR) +90% normal +60% hardly noticeable < 60% Chronic kidney disease (CKD) 30-59% anemia + weak bones ≤ 20% causes serious health problems ≤ 10%, 15% End Stage Renal Disease (ESRD) –Need dialysis or transplant (long waitlist)
12
Chronic Kidney Disease (CKD) Chronic = deterioration over time ≠ acute Most diseases attack both kidneys 0.2% prevalence Common causes –Diabetes –High blood pressure Treatment can slow progression 10-20 years until ESRD
13
Dialysis Hemodialysis (hemo = blood) –3x week, 3-4 hr sessions in clinic –Alternatively at home more frequently –Vein in hand/arm –Most common (focus of paper) Peritoneal dialysis –Pump fluid into peritoneal cavity –Exchange through peritoneal membrane –Permanent tube in abdomen –4-5x day, less equipment Also inject drugs
14
What can go wrong? Hospitalized ~ 30% of the year Causes –Heart problems –Fluid build-up –Infection Dosage = Urea Reduction Ratio (URR) –Adequate = +65% Anemia = Hematocrit level (red blood count) –Optimal = 33-36%
15
Drugs billed separately (40% of revenue) Lab work billed separately New rule would bundle them (9/15/2009)
16
Stylized Medicare Payments $130/session When hospitalized –No payment to provider –Costs Medicare $30,600 / year
17
Evidence-Based Incentive Systems for Medicare Dialysis Payments Incentives matter Optimal contract design With data! Dialysis is a good example.
18
Agenda Medicare Dialysis Model
19
Principal Agent Model 2 player game –Principal = Medicare –Agent = Dialysis provider Sequential game 1. Principal announces contract 2. Agent takes hidden action e 3. Outcome o(e) observed Principal receives E[U(o,- (o))] Agent receives E[u(e, (o))]
20
Principal Agent Model Agent optimality: e*( ) in arg max e E[u(e, (o(e)))] Principal optimality: * in arg max E[U(o(e*),- (o(e*)))] s.t. Agent participation constraint holds U 0 ≤ E[u(e*, (o(e*)))] 1. Principal announces contract 2. Agent takes hidden action e 3. Outcome o(e) observed Principal receives E[U(o,- (o))] Agent receives E[u(e, (o))]
21
Intermediate and Downstream int = Intermediate, ds = downstream (final) Outcome a vector: o = (o int,o ds ) Action a vector: e = (e int,e ds ) o(e) = simple function + correlated noise –o int = e int + int –o ds = o int + ´ ds = e int + e ds + ds –noise mean 0 and = Cov ( int, ds ) E[o int ] = e int, E[o ds ] = e int + e ds
22
Simplifications Affine contract: (o) = 0 + int o int + ds o ds Aligning incentives: o int = E[o ds | o int ] Action/effort has cost g(e) = c T e+0.5 e T Q e –Increasing costs to effort Agent has exponential utility –u(x) = -exp (-r x) –Constant absolute risk aversion –u(e, (o)) = - exp (-r [ (o) - g(e)]) Principal risk neutral –E[U(o,- (o))]= v o ds - (o)
23
Dialysis Application Outcomes o = (o int,o ds ) –o ds = fraction of hospital free days in year –o int = f(DOSAGE,ANEMIA) DOSAGE = % of treatments URR ≥ 65% ANEMIA = % of treatments hematocrit in [33%,36%] Current payment scheme: (o) = current o ds Reservation utility U 0 set by current payment scheme
24
Risk Adjustment Principal able to observe patient characteristics (part of the noise) – int int,i + h int (PAT i ) – ds ds,i + h ds (PAT i ) Payment scheme is risk adjusted – (o) = 0 + int (o int -h int (PAT i )) + ds (o ds - h ds (PAT i )) –Similar to adjustment for case-mix in current scheme
25
Parameters r unknown, baseline 2·10 -5 –paying $10 ~ 50-50 chance of winning/losing $1k v = $30,600 / year hospital free g(e), , f(DOSAGE,ANEMIA) fit from data –g(e) adjusted R 2 = 0.034
26
Results Current payment scheme ds = $27,900/year close to optimal for int = 0 Optimal scheme: (o) = $27,700o int + $400 o ds $2,140 increase in Medicare payments to provider +27 hospital free days $123 savings for Medicare Reward (and risk) increased for provider 266k Medicare patients on dialysis +20k hospital-free life years, $32M savings
27
Sensitivity Higher risk aversion leads to small 0 Diminishing returns for increasing v
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.