Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published byBrittany Walker Modified over 9 years ago
1
The Dividend Decision P.V. Viswanath Based on Damodaran’s Corporate Finance
2
P.V. Viswanath2 Theories of Dividend Payout Dividend Irrelevance Dividend Clienteles Signaling Catering to Psychological Investor Preferences Disciplinary Effects on Managers
3
P.V. Viswanath3 Dividend Irrelevance Investors can create their own dividends. Consequently, firm value will not be affected by dividend payments.
4
P.V. Viswanath4 Example of Dividend Irrelevance Stellar, Inc. has decided to invest $10 m. in a new project with a NPV of $20 m., but it has not made an announcement. The company has $10 m. in cash to finance the new project. Stellar has 10 m. shares of stock outstanding, selling for $24 each, and no debt. Hence, its aggregate value is $240 m. prior to the announcement ($24 per share).
5
P.V. Viswanath5 Example of Dividend Irrelevance Two alternatives: One, pay no dividend and finance the project with cash. The value of each share rises to $26 following the announcement. Each shareholder can sell 0.0385 (= 1/26) shares to obtain a $1 dividend, leaving him with.9615 shares value at $25 (26 x 0.9615). Hence the shareholder has one share worth $26, or one share worth $25 plus $1 in cash.
6
P.V. Viswanath6 Example of Dividend Irrelevance Two, pay a dividend of $1 per share, sell $10m. worth of new shares to finance the project. After the company announces the new project and pays the $1 dividend, each share will be worth $25. To raise the $10 m. needed for the project, the company must sell 400,000 (=10,000,000/25) shares. Immediately following the share issue, Stellar will have 10,400,000 shares trading for $25 each, giving the company an aggregate value of 25 x 10,400,000 = $260 m. If a shareholder does not want the $1 dividend, he can buy 0.04 shares (1/25). Hence, the shareholder has one share worth $25 and $1 in dividends, or 1.04 shares worth $26 in total.
7
P.V. Viswanath7 Assumptions for Dividend Irrelevance 1.The issue of new stock (to replace excess dividends) is costless and can, therefore, cover the shortfall caused by paying excess dividends. 2.Firms that face a cash shortfall do not respond by cutting back on projects and thereby affect future operating cash flows. 3.Stockholders are indifferent between receiving dividends and price appreciation. 4.Any cash remaining in the firm is invested in projects that have zero net present value. (such as financial investments) rather than used to take on poor projects (i.e. there are no agency costs of outside equity).
8
P.V. Viswanath8 Implications of Dividend Irrelevance A firm cannot resurrect its image with stockholders by offering higher dividends when its true prospects are bad. The price of a company's stock will not be affected by its dividend policy, all other things being the same. (Of course, the price will fall on the ex-dividend date.)
9
P.V. Viswanath9 Dividend Clienteles: Tax Effects For individual investors, dividends are more heavily taxed than capital gains because of the tax-timing option--the ability for individual investors to postpone the tax liability on capital gains income. Hence individuals may prefer capital gains. Corporate shareholders pay income tax at a 34% peak marginal rate, but are permitted to claim a 70% dividends-received deduction. Hence the top marginal tax rate on dividend income for a corporation is only (1-.7) x 34 = 10.2%. They have a greater preference for dividends. Tax-exempt institutions, such as pension funds, do not have a bias in favor of capital gains or dividends.
10
P.V. Viswanath10 Stockholder Marginal Tax Rate Estimation Suppose t o represents the tax rate on ordinary dividends and t cg represents the tax rate on capital gains. Let P B denote the cum-dividend stock price, and P A the ex-dividend stock price, and P the price at which the stock was acquired. For the marginal investor, P B -(P B -P)t cg = P A -(P A -P)t cg + D(1-t o ) where the LHS is the after-tax gain from selling the stock cum-dividend and the RHS is the after-tax gain from selling the stock ex- dividend.
11
P.V. Viswanath11 Stockholder Marginal Tax Rate Estimation From this, we get the relationship: By examining the empirical price drop, one may then infer the marginal tax bracket for holders of the firm's stock. However, this opens up the possibility of dividend capture.
12
P.V. Viswanath12 Dividend Mechanics Declaration date: The board of directors declares a payment Record date: The declared dividends are distributable to shareholders of record on this date. Payment date: The dividend checks are mailed to shareholders of record. Ex-dividend date: A share of stock becomes ex- dividend on the date the seller is entitled to keep the dividend. At this point, the stock is said to be trading ex-dividend.
13
P.V. Viswanath13 Dividend Capture On Aug 2, 2005, XYZ declares a dividend payable on October 3, 2005. XYZ announces that shareholders of record on or before Sept 30, 2005 are entitled to the dividend. The stock goes ex- dividend Sept 28, 2005, two days before the record date. Anyone who bought the stock before September 28, 2005 or after would get the dividend. The stock price will fall after the dividend payment, but usually less than the div amount. If the trader is tax-neutral, selling right after the stock goes ex-dividend, i.e. on Sept 28, can net the trader a profit.
14
P.V. Viswanath14 Dividend Clienteles: Transactions Costs A shareholder who desires a high income stream would prefer real cash dividend payments over homemade dividends if the firm can sell new shares more cheaply than the shareholder can sell his/her own shares. Hence such shareholders might prefer firms with a high payout ratio, while other shareholders may prefer firms with a low payout policy. Consequently, some investors prefer equity income in the form of dividends, while others prefer capital gains.
15
P.V. Viswanath15 Dividend Signalling If investors cannot observe information to distinguish a good firm from a bad firm, both firms will be valued the same. Firms that pay higher dividends than they would otherwise have, drain cash and thus increase the probability of bankruptcy. This will decrease the value of the firm. This decrease in firm value will be lower for good firms, because they are less likely to go bankrupt. Hence if a good firm increases its dividends, bad firms will be less likely to mimic the good firm. This will allow investors to separate good firms from bad firms and they will price their stock higher. This benefits stockholders who have to sell in the interim.
16
P.V. Viswanath16 Psychological Investor Preferences Dividends and Capital Gains may not be perfect substitutes due to psychological reasons. A lack of self-control may lead an investor to prefer regular cash dividends. If the investor has to sell stock to get income, he might have a tendency to sell too much stock too soon. Hence an investor might choose to invest in a firm that follows a particular type of dividend policy to minimize the total agency costs of shareholding, including the investor's human frailties.
17
P.V. Viswanath17 Disciplinary Effects on Managers Contracts between the firm and its managers cannot always be designed to take into account all possible contingencies. Hence, managers may sometimes take actions that reduce firm value. For example, it may be in the interest of managers to increase firm size or to unduly reduce the riskiness of the firm in order to reduce the probability of bankruptcy, and increase the present value of their firm specific skills. This may lead them to accept negative NPV projects or to engage in undesirable mergers.
18
P.V. Viswanath18 Disciplinary Effects on Managers This may lead some managers to reduce dividends to a suboptimal level. In contrast, managers, who want to assure the market of their desire to maximize firm value by reducing the amount of disposable resources (free cash flow beyond current investment needs) available to them, may choose to increase dividends. By doing so, they force themselves to submit to the discipline of the markets any time that they wish to raise funds to invest in a project. Such credible proof of a manager's unwillingness to take NPV < 0 projects will be rewarded by the market with an increase in the stock price.
19
P.V. Viswanath19 Dividends and Firm Life-Cycle Stage 1 Introduction Funding Needs Limited by size and other infrastructure limits Cash flows generated Negative as investments are made Dividend Policy No dividends New Stock Issues
20
P.V. Viswanath20 Dividends and Firm Life-Cycle Stage 2 Rapid expansion Funding NeedsHigh relative to firm value Cash flows generated Cash flow low relative to firm value Dividend PolicyNo or very low dividends
21
P.V. Viswanath21 Dividends and Firm Life-Cycle Stage 3 Mature growth Funding NeedsModerate relative to firm value Cash flows generated Cash flow increases as percentage of firm value Dividend PolicyIncrease dividends
22
P.V. Viswanath22 Dividends and Firm Life-Cycle Stage 4 Decline Funding NeedsLow as projects dry up Cash flows generated Cash flow high relative to firm value Dividend Policy Special dividends Repurchase stock
23
P.V. Viswanath23 Relevant factors in dividend policy Investment Opportunities: A firm with more investment opportunities should pay a lower fraction of its earnings. Stability of earnings: A firm with more volatile earnings should pay, on average, a lower proportion of its earnings, so that it will not have to cut dividends. Alternative sources of capital: To the extent that a firm can raise alternative capital at low cost, it can afford to pay higher dividends. Hence, large firms tend to pay higher dividends.
24
P.V. Viswanath24 Relevant Factors in Dividend Policy Degree of financial leverage: If a firm has high leverage, it will probably also have covenants restricting the payment of dividends. Furthermore, to a certain extent, dividends and debt can be considered substitutes for the purpose of manager discipline. Signalling incentives: To the extent that a firm can signal using other less costly means, for example debt, it should pay lower dividends. Stockholder Characteristics: If a firm's stockholders want higher dividends, it should provide them.
25
P.V. Viswanath25 Computing optimal payout: first step Questions: How much cash is available to be paid out as dividends? Answer: The funds available to be paid out as dividends are essentially equal to free cash flow to equity (FCFE) Keep in mind these quantities should be computed prospectively.
26
P.V. Viswanath26 Three definitions of FCFE FCFE = Net Income - (Capital Expenditures - Depreciation) - (Change in Noncash Working Capital) + (New Debt Issued - Debt Repayments) - Preferred Dividends FCFE = Net Income - (Capital Expenditures - Depreciation)*(1- Debt Ratio) - Change in Non-cash Working Capital (1-Debt Ratio). Cash Flows from Operating Activities - (Capital expenditures) - (preferred dividends) - (New Debt Issued - Debt Repayments).
27
P.V. Viswanath27 Computing optimal payout: second step How good are the projects available to the firm? If Dividends greatly exceed FCFE, dividends should be cut. If the rate of return on equity is greater than the cost of equity, the released funds should be invested in new projects and if funds are inadequate, funding should be sought from elsewhere. If projects are unprofitable, investment should be reduced.
28
P.V. Viswanath28 Computing optimal payout: second step If FCFE greatly exceed Dividends, the CFO must check to see how funds are being invested. If the actual rate of return (accounting rate of return) on equity is greater than the required rate of return, then the excess funds should be invested in new projects. If necessary, the dividend payout ratio should also be decreased to release funds for new projects. If the actual rate of return is low relative to the required rate of return, then dividends should be increased.
29
P.V. Viswanath29 Solution to Problem 8, Chapter 22 Conrail could have paid, on average, yearly dividends equal to its FCFE. Conrail is earning an average accounting return on equity of 13.5%. The required rate of return = 0.07 + 1.25(0.125-0.07) = 13.875. Hence Conrail’s projects have done badly on average. It’s average dividends have been much lower than the average FCFE. Conrail should pay more in dividends.
30
P.V. Viswanath30 Solution to Problem 9, Chap. 22 This is the amount that the company can afford to pay in dividends. The perceived uncertainty in these cash flows implies that the firm should be more conservative in paying out the entire amount of FCFE each year.
Similar presentations
© 2024 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.