Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

AGEC 640 – Agricultural Policy Thursday, September 18 th, 2014 Nutrition and Food Markets Today: Imperfect information & food demand Reading: Masters and.

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "AGEC 640 – Agricultural Policy Thursday, September 18 th, 2014 Nutrition and Food Markets Today: Imperfect information & food demand Reading: Masters and."— Presentation transcript:

1 AGEC 640 – Agricultural Policy Thursday, September 18 th, 2014 Nutrition and Food Markets Today: Imperfect information & food demand Reading: Masters and Sanogo, 2002 in AJAE Homework #2 on food choices due Thr., 9/25

2 What’s behind consumers’ price and income response? Slide 2 Price of food Quantity of food consumed P1P1 P2P2 Q1Q1 Q2Q2 Consumers’ income Quantity of food consumed Q2Q2 Q1Q1 Y1Y1 Y2Y2 “demand curve”“Engel curve” (=income-consumption curve) price elasticity of demand: %∆Q/ %∆P income elasticity of demand: %∆Q/ %∆Y …we need to think very carefully about what generates these curves!

3 To understand food demand, we’ll want to consider… consumers’ optimization (“Econ 101” effects) –preferences: indifference curves and welfare –price effects: demand curves and elasticity –income effects: Engel curves and elasticity really constrained optimization (Econ 102, 103…) –what else might be useful to understand food intake? –benefits are delayed, and often not observable credit/insurance constraints (poor can’t borrow to buy food) “behavioral” effects (predictable violations of rationality) –weak self-discipline (addiction, obesity, etc.) –distorted perceptions (anxiety, obsession, etc.) information asymmetries (role of 3 rd party quality assurance)

4 Quantity of “b” goods Optimization and consumer preferences Qb Quantity of “a”, all other goods Qa Initial observed point “O” The points in this quadrant offer less of both goods, so any optimizing consumer would prefer “O” to them The points in this quadrant offer more of both goods, so any optimizing consumer would prefer them to “O” All combinations amongst which the consumer is indifferent must fall along a downward sloping line.

5 Quantity of “b” goods Optimization and substitution possibilities The “indifference curve” QbQb QaQa Eventually, one becomes less willing to reduce all other things in exchange for more of “b”, so the indifference curve becomes flatter here Eventually, one becomes less willing to reduce “b” in exchange for more of all other things, so the indifference curve becomes steeper here There is an indifference curve, drawn smooth for simplicity. Quantity of “a”, all other goods

6 Quantity of “b” goods Constrained optimization: Indifference curves and the “expenditure line” Qb Qa higher indifference levels lower indiff. levels Indifference curve through initial point Exp. = PaQa + PbQb Qa = Exp./Qa – (Pb/Pa)Qb Slope of expenditure line = -Pb/Pa Expenditure level at the initial point Quantity of “a”, all other goods

7 Quantity of “b” goods Indifference level at the initial point The new indifference level is lower The new expenditure line is steeper slope = -Pb’/Pa Constrained optimization: When the price of “b” rises, how do consumers adjust? Slope of expenditure line = -Pb/Pa Quantity of “a”, all other goods the price of b has no effect on this point higher prices induce substitution and reduce “real income”

8 Price effects The Demand Curve Price Quantity Consumed When price changes, consumers move along their demand curve. Welfare is lower at higher prices (later, we’ll see this as “consumer surplus”)

9 When income rises, consumers’ demand curve shifts (usually to the right, as consumers buy larger quantities at each price) Income effects The Demand Curve Price Quantity Consumed

10 Price Elasticity of Demand Price ($/lb) Quantity Consumed (lbs/yr) 1.25 10 1.00 15 To measure the “steepness” of demand curves in a more useful way than with its slope, we use +5 -.25 the elasticity of demand (ε): = percentage change in quantity for a percentage change in price = %ΔQ / %ΔP = 5/10 / -.25/1.25 = -.5 / -.2 = - 2.5

11 Elasticity and expenditure: “Price-elastic” vs. “price-inelastic” demand Price ($/lb) Quantity Consumed (lbs/yr) “Elastic demand” : demand curve is relatively flat when price rises, expenditure (P×Q) falls | ε | > 1 “Inelastic demand” : demand curve is relatively steep when price rises, expenditure (P×Q) rises | ε | < 1 “Unit-elastic demand” : demand curve is such that when price rises, expenditure (P×Q) stays constant: | ε | = 1

12 Income Effects on Food Consumption Price ($/lb) Quantity Consumed (lbs/yr) 1.25 10 1.00 15 Remember that when income rises, consumers’ demand curve shifts (usually to the right) It’s helpful to draw a curve of consumption on income, for a given price

13 Quantity Consumed (lbs/yr/pers) Income ($/yr/pers) 02505001000500010,000 200 500 700 Engel curve for food use only Engel curve for all uses Income Effects on Food Consumption A hypothetical “Engel” curve

14 Quantity Consumed (lbs/yr/pers) Income ($/yr/pers) 02505001000500010,000 200 500 700 Income elasticity (e) : % change in Q / % change in Y varies widely by income level, and by type of use Income Elasticity of Demand (see slide 31a)

15 Income ($/year) 0500100015002000250030003500 Qty. Consumed (kg/year) 10 20 30 Elasticity along the Engel Curve no effect elastic or “luxury” inelastic or “normal” negative or “inferior” Income elasticity (e=%ΔQ/ %ΔY) is closely linked to income level : income-elastic (“luxury”) goods: e > 1 income-inelastic (“normal”) goods: 0 < e < 1 negative-elasticity (“inferior”) goods: e < 0 “necessary”

16 Average income and price elasticities of demand in Indonesia (estimated in the 1970s) “inelastic” “elastic” “inelastic” “elastic” Reminder: elasticity is %ΔQ/%ΔY (income) or %ΔQ/%ΔP (price). An extreme case: can price elasticity ever go positive? Such “Giffen” goods have finally been documented, by Jensen & Miller (2007)

17 Effect of income growth among the poorest 30% in Brazil, 1974-75 Income elasticities by income group, rural Brazil, 1974-75 (“luxuries” for the poor) (“inferior” for everyone)

18 Calorie intake by nutrient group and income level income level in 1962 (log scale) calories from each nutrient group (percent of total) The poorest eat mainly carbohydrates; income growth permits an increase in fats and proteins

19 Macronutrient intake by U.S. children aged 6 to 11 years 1977-781989-911994-96,98 Girls Energy(kcal)1,8061,8321,825 Protein(g)69.367.262.7 Fat(g)77.869.866.8 Carbohydrate(g)211.9241.6250 Carbohydrate(% kcal)47.452.654.9 Boys Energy(kcal)1,9501,8912,050 Protein(g)75.670.171.2 Fat(g)84.772.775.1 Carbohydrate(g)226.2245.5279.6 Carbohydrate(% kcal)46.85254.8 Source: Enns, Mickle and Goldman (2002), Table 5. At high (U.S.-level) incomes, we’ve been switching back to more carbohydrates.

20 Now… what else might be useful to understand food intake? Food is a public concern, but it is not a “public good” Food demand generate subtle kinds of market failures One reason is that its benefits are important but often delayed and often not observable, so we have: –credit and insurance constraints (the poor can’t borrow) –“behavioral” effects (people are predictably irrational) weak self-discipline (addiction, obesity, etc.) distorted perceptions (anxiety, obsession, etc.) –asymmetric information (need quality assurance) example of Masters and Sanogo (2002) study of infant foods in Bamako, Mali

21 Weight-for-height (WHZ) and height-for-age (HAZ) of children in Mali, relative to international norms The most severe nutritional deficits occur in a relatively brief period

22 Child mortality is closely linked to their weight-for-height Source: Reprinted from Fawzi, W.W., M.G. Herrera, D.L. Spiegelman, A.E. Amin, P. Nestel, and K.A. Mohamed. 1997. “A Prospective Study of Malnutrition in Relation to Child Mortality in the Sudan.” The American Journal of Clinical Nutrition 65(4): 1062-9.

23 Why are nutritional deficits so severe between 4 and 24 months of age? exposure to disease –due to initial introduction of water and solids, or –perhaps also more mobility and contact with others; deficits in nutrient intake –due to differences between infant and family foods, –and failure to provide enough infant-quality foods.

24 Characteristics of infant foods Infants need foods of higher nutrient density than the family diet, from when they outgrow the nutrients in breastmilk to when they can digest enough of the family diet. High density is obtained from high-cost ingredients (oilseeds or animal products), mixed with low-cost staples (cereal grains, etc.) but parents cannot observe an infant food’s ingredient ratios and density, even after consumption, because other factors affect growth

25 Economics of credence goods Akerlof (1970) and others: If quality is unobservable, quantity will be… zero! optimizing people will not respond to price …except as remedied by trust in a brand. ==> sellers use advertising and high prices as visible commitments to quality, so –buyers must pay a premium over known costs, to buy guaranteed quality, –e.g. premiums paid for “brand-name” lawyers, pharmacists, auto mechanics, etc.

26 Table 1. Infant foods for sale in Bamako, Mali (1999) Brand namePackagingRetail Prices (FCFA/unit)* Mkt.StoresPharmacy Cérélac (wheat)400 g. can140015001615 Cérélac (wheat)200 g. box 600 850 Cérélac (rice)400 g. can1600 Cérélac (wheat/Banana)400 g. can1750 Cérélac (wheat +3 fruits)400 g. can2240 Blédilac** (wheat)250 g. can1270 Blédina** lactée fruits250 g. box1830 Farinor** (maize/soy)400 g. box16901750 Source: Masters and Sanogo, 2002. MISOLA500 g. bag 300 UCODAL (e.g. Sinba)200 g. bag 200

27 Akerlof (1970) saw an alternative remedy to lower the cost of credence goods: third-party certification –mandatory testing => complete coverage examples: FDA, USDA limitations: tax-funded, incentive for fraud –fee-for-service => self-sustaining, self-policing examples: ISO, UL limitations: scale economies, may not emerge spontaneously Economics of credence goods (continued)

28 Benefits and Costs of Certification in Mali 1.benefits of certification –what is food-quality information really worth? –do some mothers value information more than others? 2.costs of certification –what are set-up and marginal costs? –what volume would be certified? 3.net gains from certification –do they justify the investment risks? –would the program be sustainable?

29 To detect what certification is worth, we need a experimental economics.. Vickrey (1961) and others: Preference-revealing auctions mimic real markets: price is fixed by others; choice is to accept or decline M&S experiment is aimed at very, very low-income people -- avoids using money, so choice is among infant foods only; avoids calculations, so choice is easy and natural: give mothers a can of Cerelac offer to swap for increasing quantities of substitute products record whether they accept or decline each choice give them one of their choices, selected at random The design is not quite strategy-proof; respondents may hold out for slightly more of each substitute than in ideal auction.

30

31 Summary statistics for willingness-to-pay results WTP (FCFA per 400 g.) ave.s.d.min.max. WTP by product 1. Cerelac1500.00 (market price) 2. Certilac1159.83357.776671500 3. Anonymous product 704.59210.364621500 4. Raw ingredients 119.14 35.07 75 150 WTP for premium for 2 over 3: Certification 455.24251.22 01038 for 3 over 4: Processing 585.45213.973121425

32 So certification has large benefits… but what would be its cost? 10 million FCFA/month for advertising 1 m. FCFA/mo. per 50 tests/mo. for staffing 0.6 m FCFA/mo. per 20 tests/mo. for transport 3,520 FCFA/mo. per test for consumables 1,000 x 400g. sold per test done => cost falls below ave. WTP at 30,000 bags/mo. => cost falls below 100 FCFA at 215,000 /mo.

33 How much food would be certified? 50,000 children aged 6-24 months in Bamako 100 g./day average consumption per child => 8 bags of 400 g. per month low scenario: 39% use (now using Cerelac) high scenario: 89% use (now using any food) => total potential is 155,000 – 350,000 bags/mo.

34 Would certification’s benefits exceed its costs? Two ways to estimate: (1) Each respondent has a different WTP –Some respondents’ WTP below cost –Construct demand curves & optimal quantity –Find economic surplus (2s) All respondents have identical WTP –Average WTP is way above cost –Full market size is certified –Find total benefits - costs

35 Estimated certification demand and average-cost curves

36 Table 3. Consumer surplus and net benefit from certification Case 1 Case 2 Consumer surplus approach Equilibrium qty. certified(400 g. bags/mo.)150,000345,000 Net economic surplus gain(FCFA/month)51,543,984134,029,438 Net economic surplus gain(US$/year)951,5812,474,390 Cost-benefit analysis approach Total estimated market size(400 g. bags/mo.)154,746353,138 Net economic benefit/month(FCFA/month)51,713,454132,138,264 Net economic surplus gain(US$/year)954,7102,439,476

37 OK, so quality information is needed… should testing be voluntary or mandatory? Private solutions work if a “certifier” can –force users to pay (that is, exclude free-riders), e.g.: Underwriters’ Laboratories (sellers pay for label) Consumer Reports, CarFax (buyers pay each time) –and thereby capture enough revenue to pay the cost of obtaining the information; while maintaining a credible quality signal of their own! Often it’s cheaper to use the government: –“ value capture” from consumers can occur through taxation (e.g. USDA grades) or user fees (e.g. air traffic) –quality-destroying competition can be barred by mandatory standards and licensing –but the “quality” being upheld may not be valued by consumers; standards may be just an entry barrier to protect insiders

38 …Some conclusions Food intake decisions involve –not only observable attributes (taste, texture, color), –but also unobservable qualities and delayed effects. Food choices can be hard to understand using economics on observable prices and quantities only –so sometimes we need inferences and experiments –but much of the “irrationality” in food consumption can be understood as constrained optimization –this allows us to plan public interventions that raise welfare, even though food is not a public good.


Download ppt "AGEC 640 – Agricultural Policy Thursday, September 18 th, 2014 Nutrition and Food Markets Today: Imperfect information & food demand Reading: Masters and."

Similar presentations


Ads by Google