Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

William Greene Department of Economics Stern School of Business New York University Some Applications of Latent Class Modeling In Health Economics.

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "William Greene Department of Economics Stern School of Business New York University Some Applications of Latent Class Modeling In Health Economics."— Presentation transcript:

1 William Greene Department of Economics Stern School of Business New York University Some Applications of Latent Class Modeling In Health Economics

2 

3 Outline Theory: Finite Mixture and Latent Class Models Applications o Obesity o Self Assessed Health o Efficiency of Nursing Hommes

4 Latent Classes A population contains a mixture of individuals of different types (classes) Common form of the data generating mechanism within the classes Observed outcome y is governed by the common process F(y|x,  j ) Classes are distinguished by the parameters,  j.

5

6 A Latent Class Hurdle NB2 Model Analysis of ECHP panel data (1994-2001) Two class Latent Class Model o Typical in health economics applications Hurdle model for physician visits o Poisson hurdle for participation and negative binomial intensity given participation o Contrast to a negative binomial model

7

8 How Finite Mixture Models Work

9 Find the ‘Best’ Fitting Mixture of Two Normal Densities

10 Mixing probabilities.715 and.285

11 Approximation Actual Distribution

12 A Practical Distinction Finite Mixture (Discrete Mixture): o Functional form strategy o Component densities have no meaning o Mixing probabilities have no meaning o There is no question of “class membership” o The number of classes is uninteresting – enough to get a good fit Latent Class: o Mixture of subpopulations o Component densities are believed to be definable “groups” (Low Users and High Users in Bago d’Uva and Jones application) o The classification problem is interesting – who is in which class? o Posterior probabilities, P(class|y,x) have meaning o Question of the number of classes has content in the context of the analysis

13 Why Make the Distinction? Same estimation strategy Same estimation results Extending the latent class model o Allows a rich, flexible model specification for behavior o The classes may be governed by different processes

14 Antecedents Pearson’s 1894 study of crabs in Naples – finite mixture of two normals – seeking evidence of two subspecies. Some of the extensions I will note here have already been (implicitly) employed in earlier literature. o Different underlying processes o Heterogeneous class probabilities o Correlations of unobservables in class probabilities with unobservables in structural (within class) models One has not and is not widespread (yet) o Cross class restrictions implied by the theory of the model

15 Switching Regressions Mixture of normals with heterogeneous mean o y ~ N(b 0 x 0,  0 2 ) if d=0, y ~ N(b 1 x 1,  1 2 ) if d=1, P(d=1)=  (cz). o d is unobserved (latent switching). Becomes a latent class model when regime 0 is a demand function and regime 1 is a supply function, d=0 if excess supply The two regression equations may involve different variables – a true latent class model

16 Endogenous Switching (ca.1980) Not identified. Regimes do not coexist.

17 Outcome Inflation Models Lambert 1992, Technometrics. Quality control problem. Counting defects per unit of time on the assembly line. How to explain the zeros; is the process under control or not? Two State Outcome: Prob(State=0)=R, Prob(State=1)=1-R o State=0, Y=0 with certainty o State=1, Y ~ some distribution support that includes 0, e.g., Poisson. o Prob(State 0|y>0) = 0 o Prob(State 1|y=0) = (1-R)f(0)/[R + (1-R)f(0)] o R = Logistic probability “Nonstandard” latent class model Recent users have extended this to “Outcome Inflated Models,” e.g., twos inflation in models of fertility; inflated responses in health status.

18 Split Population Survival Models Schmidt and Witte 1989 study of recidivism F=1 for eventual failure, F=0 for never fail. F is unobserved. P(F=1)= , P(F=0)=1-  C=1 for a recidivist, observed. Prob(F=1|C=1) = 1. Density for time until failure actually occurs is  × g(t|F=1). Density for observed duration (possibly censored) o P(C=0)=(1-  ) +  (G(T|F=1)) (Observation is censored) o Density given C=1 =  g(t|F=1) o G=survival function, t=time of observation. Unobserved F implies a latent population split. They added covariates to  :  i =logit(z i ). Different models apply to the two latent subpopulations.

19 Variations of Interest Heterogeneous priors for the class probabilities Correlation of unobservables in class probabilities with unobservables in regime specific models Variations of model structure across classes Behavioral basis for the mixed models with implied restrictions

20 Applications Obesity: Heterogeneous class probabilities, generalized ordered choice; Endogenous class membership Self Assessed Health: Heterogeneous subpopulations; endogenous class membership Cost Efficiency of Nursing Homes: theoretical restrictions on underlying models

21 Modeling Obesity with a Latent Class Model Mark Harris Department of Economics, Curtin University Bruce Hollingsworth Department of Economics, Lancaster University Pushkar Maitra Department of Economics, Monash University William Greene Stern School of Business, New York University

22 300 Million People Worldwide. International Obesity Task Force: www.iotf.org

23 Costs of Obesity In the US more people are obese than smoke or use illegal drugs Obesity is a major risk factor for non-communicable diseases like heart problems and cancer Obesity is also associated with: o lower wages and productivity, and absenteeism o low self-esteem An economic problem. It is costly to society: o USA costs are around 4-8% of all annual health care expenditure - US $100 billion o Canada, 5%; France, 1.5-2.5%; and New Zealand 2.5%

24 Measuring Obesity An individual’s weight given their height should lie within a certain range o Body Mass Index (BMI) o Weight (Kg)/height(Meters) 2 WHO guidelines: o Underweight BMI < 18.5 o Normal18.5 < BMI < 25 o Overweight25 < BMI < 30 o Obese BMI > 30 o Morbidly Obese BMI > 40

25 Two Latent Classes: Approximately Half of European Individuals

26 Modeling BMI Outcomes Grossman-type health production function Health Outcomes = f(inputs) Existing literature assumes BMI is an ordinal, not cardinal, representation of individuals. o Weight-related health status o Do not assume a one-to-one relationship between BMI levels and (weight-related) health status levels Translate BMI values into an ordinal scale using WHO guidelines Preserves underlying ordinal nature of the BMI index but recognizes that individuals within a so-defined weight range are of an (approximately) equivalent (weight-related) health status level

27 Conversion to a Discrete Measure Measurement issues: Tendency to under- report BMI o women tend to under-estimate/report weight; o men over-report height. Using bands should alleviate this Allows focus on discrete ‘at risk’ groups

28 A Censored Regression Model for BMI Simple Regression Approach Based on Actual BMI: BMI* =  ′x + ,  ~ N[0,  2 ] Interval Censored Regression Approach WT = 0 if BMI* < 25 Normal 1 if 25 < BMI* < 30 Overweight 2 if BMI* > 30 Obese  Inadequate accommodation of heterogeneity  Inflexible reliance on WHO classification  Rigid measurement by the guidelines

29 An Ordered Probit Approach A Latent Regression Model for “True BMI” BMI* =  ′x + ,  ~ N[0,σ 2 ], σ 2 = 1 “True BMI” = a proxy for weight is unobserved Observation Mechanism for Weight Type WT = 0 if BMI* < 0Normal 1 if 0 < BMI* <  Overweight 2 if  < BMI* Obese

30 Heterogeneity in the BMI Ranges Boundaries are set by the WHO narrowly defined for all individuals Strictly defined WHO definitions may consequently push individuals into inappropriate categories We allow flexibility at the margins of these intervals Following Pudney and Shields (2000) therefore we consider Generalised Ordered Choice models - boundary parameters are now functions of observed personal characteristics

31 Generalized Ordered Probit Approach A Latent Regression Model for True BMI BMI i * =  ′x i +  i,  i ~ N[0,σ 2 ], σ 2 = 1 Observation Mechanism for Weight Type WT i = 0 if BMI i * < 0 Normal 1 if 0 < BMI i * <  i (w i ) Overweight 2 if  (w i ) < BMI i * Obese

32 Latent Class Modeling Several ‘types’ or ‘classes. Obesity be due to genetic reasons (the FTO gene) or lifestyle factors Distinct sets of individuals may have differing reactions to various policy tools and/or characteristics The observer does not know from the data which class an individual is in. Suggests a latent class approach for health outcomes (Deb and Trivedi, 2002, and Bago d’Uva, 2005)

33 Latent Class Application Two class model (considering FTO gene): o More classes make class interpretations much more difficult o Parametric models proliferate parameters Endogenous class membership: Two classes allow us to correlate the equations driving class membership and observed weight outcomes via unobservables. Theory for more than two classes not yet developed.

34 Heterogeneous Class Probabilities  j = Prob(class=j) = governor of a detached natural process. Homogeneous.  ij = Prob(class=j|z i,individual i) Now possibly a behavioral aspect of the process, no longer “detached” or “natural” Nagin and Land 1993, “Criminal Careers…

35 Endogeneity of Class Membership

36 Model Components x: determines observed weight levels within classes For observed weight levels we use lifestyle factors such as marital status and exercise levels z: determines latent classes For latent class determination we use genetic proxies such as age, gender and ethnicity: the things we can’t change w: determines position of boundary parameters within classes For the boundary parameters we have: weight-training intensity and age (BMI inappropriate for the aged?) pregnancy (small numbers and length of term unknown)

37 Data US National Health Interview Survey (2005); conducted by the National Center for Health Statistics Information on self-reported height and weight levels, BMI levels Demographic information Split sample (30,000+) by gender

38 Outcome Probabilities Class 0 dominated by normal and overweight probabilities ‘normal weight’ class Class 1 dominated by probabilities at top end of the scale ‘non-normal weight’ Unobservables for weight class membership, negatively correlated with those determining weight levels:

39 Normal Overweight Obese Class 0 Class 1

40 Classification (Latent Probit) Model

41 BMI Ordered Choice Model Conditional on class membership, lifestyle factors Marriage comfort factor only for normal class women Both classes associated with income, education Exercise effects similar in magnitude Exercise intensity only important for ‘non-normal’ class: Home ownership only important for.non-normal.class, and negative: result of differing socieconomic status distributions across classes?

42 Effects of Aging on Weight Class

43 Effect of Education on Probabilities

44 Effect of Income on Probabilities

45 Inflated Responses in Self-Assessed Health Mark Harris Department of Economics, Curtin University Bruce Hollingsworth Department of Economics, Lancaster University William Greene Stern School of Business, New York University

46 Introduction Health sector an important part of developed countries’ economies: E.g., Australia 9% of GDP To see if these resources are being effectively utilized, we need to fully understand the determinants of individuals’ health levels To this end much policy, and even more academic research, is based on measures of self-assessed health (SAH) from survey data

47 SAH vs. Objective Health Measures Favorable SAH categories seem artificially high.  60% of Australians are either overweight or obese (Dunstan et. al, 2001)  1 in 4 Australians has either diabetes or a condition of impaired glucose metabolism  Over 50% of the population has elevated cholesterol  Over 50% has at least 1 of the “deadly quartet” of health conditions (diabetes, obesity, high blood pressure, high cholestrol)  Nearly 4 out of 5 Australians have 1 or more long term health conditions (National Health Survey, Australian Bureau of Statistics 2006)  Australia ranked #1 in terms of obesity rates Similar results appear to appear for other countries

48 SAH vs. Objective Health Our objectives 1.Are these SAH outcomes are “over- inflated” 2.And if so, why, and what kinds of people are doing the over- inflating/mis-reporting?

49 HILDA Data The Household, Income and Labour Dynamics in Australia (HILDA) dataset: 1. a longitudinal survey of households in Australia 2. well tried and tested dataset 3. contains a host of information on SAH and other health measures, as well as numerous demographic variables

50 Self Assessed Health “In general, would you say your health is: Excellent, Very good, Good, Fair or Poor?" Responses 1,2,3,4,5 (we will be using 0,1,2,3,4) Typically ¾ of responses are “good” or “very good” health; in our data (HILDA) we get 72% Similar numbers for most developed countries Does this truly represent the health of the nation?

51

52 Recent Literature - Heterogeneity Carro (2012) o Ordered SAH, “good,” “so so,” bad” o Two effects: Random effects (Mundlak) in latent index function, fixed effects in threshold Schurer and Jones(2011) o Heterogeneity, panel data, o “Generalized ordered probit:” different slope vectors for each outcome.

53 Kerkhofs and Lindeboom, Health Economics, 1995 Subjective Health Measures and State Dependent Reporting Errors Incentive to “misreport” depends on employment status: employed, unemployed, retired, disabled Ho = an objective, observed health indicator H* = latent health = f1(Ho,X1) Hs = reported health = f2(H*,X2,S) o S = employment status, 4 observed categories o Ordered choice, o Boundaries depend on S,X2; Heterogeneity is induced by incentives produced by employment status

54 A Two Class Latent Class Model True ReporterMisreporter

55 Reporter Type Model

56 Y=4 Y=3 Y=2 Y=1 Y=0

57 Pr(true,y) = Pr(true) * Pr(y | true)

58 Mis-reporters choose either good or very good The response is determined by a probit model Y=3 Y=2

59

60 Observed Mixture of Two Classes

61

62

63 Who are the Misreporters?

64 Priors and Posteriors

65 General Results

66 Whither the EM Algorithm? An Algorithm, not a model o E step: Compute posterior probabilities,  ij o M step: In each class, estimate class specific parameters using a (class and individual) weighted log likelihood, using the posteriors as weights. Cannot impose cross class restrictions Cannot model endogeneity

67

68 Latent Class Efficiency Studies Battese and Coelli – growing in weather “regimes” for Indonesian rice farmers Kumbhakar and Orea – cost structures for U.S. Banks Greene (Health Economics, 2005) – revisits WHO Year 2000 World Health Report

69 Studying Economic Efficiency in Health Care Hospital and Nursing Home o Cost efficiency o Role of quality (not studied today) Agency for Health Reseach and Quality (AHRQ)

70 Stochastic Frontier Analysis logC = f(output, input prices, environment) + v + u ε = v + u o v = noise – the usual “disturbance” o u = inefficiency Frontier efficiency analysis o Estimate parameters of model o Estimate u (to the extent we are able – we use E[u|ε]) o Evaluate and compare observed firms in the sample

71 Nursing Home Costs 44 Swiss nursing homes, 13 years Cost, Pk, Pl, output, two environmental variables Estimate cost function Estimate inefficiency

72 Estimated Cost Efficiency

73 Inefficiency? Not all agree with the presence (or identifiability) of “inefficiency” in market outcomes data. Variation around the common production structure may all be nonsystematic and not controlled by management Implication, no inefficiency: u = 0.

74 A Two Class Model Class 1: With Inefficiency o logC = f(output, input prices, environment) +  v v +  u u Class 2: Without Inefficiency o logC = f(output, input prices, environment) +  v v o  u = 0 Implement with a single zero restriction in a constrained (same cost function) two class model Parameterization: λ =  u /  v = 0 in class 2.

75 LogL= 464 with a common frontier model, 527 with two classes

76

77 Conclusion Latent class modeling provides a rich, flexible platform for behavioral model building. Thank you.


Download ppt "William Greene Department of Economics Stern School of Business New York University Some Applications of Latent Class Modeling In Health Economics."

Similar presentations


Ads by Google