Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published byBlaise Park Modified over 9 years ago
1
Monetary or Fiscal Policies?
3
Coinage debasement is the reduction of the precious metal content – silver or gold – in not just the coin itself but in the unit of the money of account MONEY OF ACCOUNT: the penny, the shilling, and the pound With 12d (pence) to the shilling, and 20 s (shillings) to the pound, so that 240d = £ 1
4
(1) By a reduction in the fineness: i.e., in the percentage of fine silver or gold in the coin, by adding proportionately more copper (2) By a reduction in the coin’s weight (3) By an increase in the nominal money-of- account value of the coin - reserved normally only for gold coins and high value silver coins
5
This paper seeks to answer two questions: (1) were the coinage debasements in Burgundian Flanders (1384-1482) undertaken principally as monetary or fiscal policies; and (2)were they beneficial or harmful? In a recent monograph, Sargent and Velde contend that monetary objectives governed almost all medieval debasements, especially to remedy the chronic shortages of petty coins.
6
Despite overwhelming evidence that Burgundian Flanders, along with most of north-west Europe in the later 14 th and 15 th centuries, experienced severe monetary scarcities and liquidity crises, especially in the periods ca. 1390 - ca. 1415 and ca. 1440 - ca. 1470, both periods of severe deflations, there is no compelling evidence that the Burgundian rulers debased their coinages on the basis of any such monetary policies.
7
My thesis is the Burgundian rulers of Flanders, in competition with neighboring princes, undertook their debasements primarily as aggressive fiscal policies, specifically to finance warfare. Debasements, however, were also undertaken as defensive policies: as noted below
8
The prince’s goal was to increase his seigniorage revenues, the tax imposed on bullion brought to their mints, by two means: (1) by increasing the tax rate itself, and (2) by enticing an increased influx of bullion into their mints, – both by the debasement techniques themselves – and by auxiliary bullionist policies to prevent bullion exports and divert them to the mints
9
(1) that merchants supplying bullion received more coins of the same face value and thus with a greater aggregate money-of-account value than before (or than from other mints); (2) that the public accepted such debased coins at the same face value, by tale; and (3) that the merchants spent their increased supply of coins quickly, before any ensuing inflation eroded those gains.
10
This study further demonstrates that the inflationary consequences of debasements were always less than those predicted by the mathematical formula: Δ T = [1/(1 - x)] – 1 possibly because those debasements failed to counteract the prevailing forces of monetary contraction and deflation in the later 14 th and 15 th centuries (1390s to the 1480s).
11
(1) to protect their mints from foreign competition, i.e., from aggressive debasements (2) to protect their domestic money supplies from influxes of debased and also counterfeit imitations (3) i.e., to counteract Gresham’s Law: that ‘cheap money drives out dear money’
12
If aggressive coinage debasements were primarily fiscal policies to finance warfare, in late-medieval Europe, monetary contractions and related deflations were often also the products of warfare From bullionist policies related to warfare: with almost universal bans on bullion exports From disruptions of trade routes that impeded coin and bullion flows And from increased hoarding
13
GENERALLY MORE HARMFUL THAN BENEFICIAL (1) Failed to provide any long term remedy for the combined problems of chronic monetary scarcities (‘bullion famines’) and deflation - indeed Burgundian rulers generally ended their rounds of debasements with severely deflationary coinage renforcements (restoring some of the lost silver to the coinage)
14
(2) The combination of coinage debasements and related bullionist measures generally served only to worsen the monetary scarcities by impeding bullion flows and coinage circulations; And also by encouraging hoarding : by withdrawing coins from circulation, which ipso facto impeded coinage circulation Note the monetary flows are often more important the monetary stocks
15
(3) To the extent that debasements did lead to some degreee of inflation, that inflation reduced real incomes of most members of the society – since wages, rents, and other fixed incomes lagged behind consumer prices - and that imposed an additional tax burden on the entire society (known as the seigniorage tax)
16
(4) Debasement injured creditors, in a similar fashion, by reducing the real values of both their principal (capital invested) and their investment returns: whether interest, rent, dividends, profits - in that respect Burgundian coinage debasement damaged Flanders’ international economic relations: epecially with the Italians and the Hanseatic Germans
17
(5) Coinage debasements and renforcements as well sometimes provoked social unrest, indeed even industrial strikes Industrial unrest amongst wage earners was understandable if, following a debasement, consumer prices rose more than did nominal wages But paradoxically, strikes were more common after coinage renforcements when the prince or town government imposed wage cuts as part of the monetary reforms
20
(1) Values in money-of-account 1 penny or 1 d groot = 24 mites = 12d or 1s parisis (2) Fineness: reckoned out of 12 deniers argent-le-roy, with 24 grains per denier = 23/24 or 95.833% pure silver (3) Weight: reckoned in terms of the ‘taille’ or number cut from the Marc de Troyes of 8 onces = 244.753 grams
21
Official money-of-account value of the coinage struck from one marc argent le roy Traite = (taille * value)/percent fineness taille (number of coins struck to the marc)* the face value of the coin/ divided by The finenesss of the coin (in deniers and grains) E.g. 68.0 * 2/ (6/12) = 136d = 22s 8d groot
22
Debasement and Inflation: a reduction in the silver content of a coin increases the corresponding traite value of silver by the reciprocal: ΔT = [1/(1 - x)] – 1 Δ T = % change in the traite: x = % change (reduction) in the silver content (as a decimal) Nov. 1428 debasement of silver double groot by 11.8%: [1/(1 - 0.118)] - 1 = (1/0.882) - 1 = 1.133 - 1 = 13.3%. increase in the value of the traite.
Similar presentations
© 2024 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.