Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Chapter 9: Political Economy

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "Chapter 9: Political Economy"— Presentation transcript:

1 Chapter 9: Political Economy
Outline Lindahl pricing Majority voting (on direct referendum) When does it work? When does it not work? Median voter theory Lobbying and Public Choice

2 Chapter 9: Political Economy
This lesson focuses on the fourth question of public finance: Why do governments do what they do? We start by discussing the “best case scenario” in which government appropriately measures and aggregates the preferences of its citizens in deciding what projects to undertake. Then we examine both direct democracy and representative democracy. Finally, we examine government failure, the inability (or unwillingness) of government to appropriately address market failures.

3 UNANIMOUS CONSENT ON PUBLIC GOODS LEVELS: Lindahl Pricing
Lindahl pricing is a system where individuals report their willingness-to-pay for each quantity of the public good, and the government aggregates preferences to form a measure of the social benefit. First, the government announces tax prices for the public good, that is, the share of the cost that each individual must bear. Each person announces how much of the public good he or she wants at those tax prices. If the individual announcements differ, the government raises the tax price for the person who wants more of the good, and lowers it for the person who wants less. When a tax price is arrived at where both individuals want the same amount of the public good, the government has reached Lindahl equilibrium. The government produces the public good at that level, and finances it by charging each person their tax price.

4 Jack’s surplus is this area
Willingness to pay Adding up their individual demands curves vertically gives the aggregate demand. $4 Jack’s surplus is this area Jack’s demand curve for fireworks is fairly steep. While Ava’s demand curve for fireworks is fairly flat. $3 DJACK SMB=DAVA+JACK And a price of 25¢ for Ava in Lindahl equilibrium. This generates a tax price of 75¢ for Jack in Lindahl equilibrium. The socially efficient level is 75 units. With this marginal cost, it is socially beneficial to produce the good. Ava’s surplus is this area $2 S=SMC $1 $0.75 DAVA $0.25 25 50 75 100 Fireworks Figure 1 Lindahl pricing

5 Lindahl Pricing Lindahl pricing corresponds to the concept of benefit taxation, which occurs when individuals are being taxed for a public good according to their valuation of the benefit they receive. With Lindahl pricing, the government does not need to know the utility functions of individual voters: it gets the voters to reveal their preferences by stating their willingness to pay for different levels of the public good.

6 Problems with Lindahl Pricing
Lindahl pricing is unlikely to work in practice, however. Preference revelation problem: Individuals may behave strategically, and pretend their willingness to pay is low in order to get others to bear a larger cost of the public good. Preference knowledge problem: It is hard for people to properly value goods they do not shop for on a regular basis. Preference aggregation problem: Aggregating millions of voters’ preferences is difficult in reality.

7 MECHANISMS FOR AGGREGATING INDIVIDUAL PREFERENCES
Let’s turn now to how voting can serve to aggregate individual preferences into a social decision. Focus on direct democracy, whereby voters directly cast ballots in favor of or in opposition to particular public projects. A common mechanism used to aggregate individual votes into a social decision is majority voting, in which individual policy options are put to a vote, and the option that receives the majority of votes is chosen.

8 Majority Voting: When It Works
Majority voting does not always provide a consistent means of aggregating preferences. To be consistent, an aggregation mechanism must satisfy three goals: Dominance: If one choice is preferred by all voters, then the aggregation mechanism much be such that this choice is made by society. Transitivity: Choices must satisfy this mathematical property. Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives: The introduction of a third choice does not change the ranking of the first two choices.

9 Majority voting delivers a consistent outcome
A town is deciding on education taxes (and spending). There are 3 possibilities: high, medium, and low spending. There are also 3 groups, represented in equal proportions. Consider pair-wise voting: High vs Low, High vs Medium, and Medium vs Low. High vs Low: Parents vote for H, Elderly & Young vote for L. L wins 2-1. High vs Medium: Parents vote for H, Elderly & Young vote for M. M wins 2-1. Since M has beaten both H and L, M is the overall winner in this case. Medium vs Low: Parents and Young vote for M, Elderly vote for L. M wins 2-1. Table 1 Finally, the “young couples” do not have kids and do not want to pay high taxes right now. Their preferences are for medium spending, then low, then high. Majority voting delivers a consistent outcome Types of voters Preference rankings Parents Elders Young Couples First H L M Second Third The preferences of parents are for high spending, then medium spending, then low spending. While the preferences of the elderly are exactly opposite.

10 Majority voting doesn’t deliver a consistent outcome
Assuming that doesn’t happen, however, private parents want high quality public education. Private parents, first and foremost, want low taxes so they can afford to sent their kids to private schools. Thus, their ordering is low, then high, then medium. A town is again deciding on education taxes (and spending). The elderly have been replaced with “private parents.” The other 2 groups are the same as before. Hmmm … There is no clear winner. L is preferred to H. H is preferred to M. M is preferred to L. This violates the transitivity assumption and leads to cycling. Medium vs Low: Only private parents for L, so M wins 2-1. High vs Low: Only “public parents” vote for H, L wins 2-1. High vs Medium: Only Young Marrieds vote for M, so H wins 2-1. Consider pair-wise voting: High vs Low, High vs Medium, and Medium vs Low. Table 2 Majority voting doesn’t deliver a consistent outcome Types of voters Preference rankings Parents Private Parents Young Couples First H L M Second Third

11 Majority Voting: When It Doesn’t Work
This set of outcomes is problematic because there is no clear winner. These results violate the principle of transitivity resulting in cycling–when majority voting does not deliver a consistent aggregation of individual preferences. Note that the failure to get a consistent winner from majority voting does not reflect a failure on the part of individuals–each group has a sensible set of preferences. The problem is aggregation–we are unable to use voting to aggregate these individual preferences into a consistent social outcome.

12 Majority Voting: When It Doesn’t Work
This creates the problem of the agenda setter, the person who decides the sequencing of the votes. In the second situation, the agenda setter can affect the outcome. For low spending to win, for example, first set up a vote between H and M. H wins. Then a vote between L and H means L will win. Any outcome can win with appropriate ordering.

13 Arrow’s Impossibility Theorem
In fact, there is no voting system that will produce a consistent outcome here. Arrow’s Impossibility Theorem states that there is no social decision (voting) rule that converts individual preferences into a consistent aggregate function without either restricting preferences or imposing a dictatorship.

14 Restricting Preferences to Solve the Impossibility Theorem
One way to solve this problem is to restrict preferences to “single-peaked” preferences. A “peak” in preferences is a point that is preferred to all its immediate neighbors. Utility falls in any direction away from this point. Multi-peaked preferences means that utility may first rise, then fall, then rise again. If preferences are single peaked, majority voting will yield a consistent outcome. We can visualize our earlier examples. See Figure 2.

15 Private parents are different in the second case.
(b) Utility Utility Young marrieds Private parents Young marrieds Public parents Parents Elders Private parents are different in the second case. Their utility goes in in either direction from M. And young marrieds are single peaked at “M”. The elderly are single peaked at “L”. Parents are single peaked at “H”. School spending School spending L M H L M H Figure 2 Voting rules

16 Restricting Preferences to Solve the Impossibility Theorem
The failure of these preferences for the “private parents” in this second case is what leads to the inability of majority voting to consistently aggregate preferences. Fortunately, single-peakedness is a reasonable assumption in many cases.

17 Median Voter Theory When preferences are single-peaked, then majority voting will deliver a consistent aggregation of preferences of the individual voters. Even stronger, the median voter theorem states that majority voting will yield the outcome preferred by the median voter if preferences are single peaked. The median voter is the voter whose tastes are in the middle of the set of voters, so an equal number of other voters prefer more and prefer less of the public good.

18 Potential Inefficiency of the Median Voter Outcome
Thus, the voting would suggest that the government only needs to find the preferences of the median voter, and implement that level of public goods. This does not account for intensity of preferences, however, so it does not follow that the social marginal benefits equal the social marginal cost. For example, if small numbers of individuals derive enormous benefits from the public good, this should be accounted for in the total social marginal benefits.

19 REPRESENTATIVE DEMOCRACY: Vote-Maximizing Politicians
In reality, voters elect representatives, who are supposed to aggregate their preferences and take them into account when they vote on the appropriate level of public goods. If politicians care about maximizing the number of votes they get, they choose the outcome preferred by the median voter.

20 In this case, the candidates split the vote equally.
John is trying to appeal to those who don’t want much defense, so he places himself at J1. Figure 3 While George chooses a much higher level of defense, G1. Voters for John Voters for George By doing so he gets the majority of the votes. But now imagine that John changes his position to J2. (a) Defense spending 0% J1 25% G1 50% Voters for John Voters for George (b) In response, George lowers his position to G2. By doing so, George now gets a majority of the votes. Defense spending 0% J2 25% G1 50% Voters for John Voters for George (c) This process will continue until the median voter’s preferences are arrived at. Defense spending 0% J2 25% G2 50% Voters for John Voters for George (d) Defense spending 0% J3 = G3 = 25% 50%

21 Assumptions of the Median Voter Model
The median voter model is a powerful tool, but relies on a number of assumptions worth mentioning: Single-dimensional voting: Voters only care about one issue. Only two candidates: With a 3rd candidate, there is no stable equilibrium. No ideology or influence: Assumes politicians only care about votes, not ideological positions. No selective voting: All citizens actually vote. No money as a tool of influence. Perfect information along three dimensions: voter knowledge of the issues, politician knowledge of the issues, and politician knowledge of voter preferences.

22 Evidence on the Median Voter Model
While the median voter model is a potentially powerful tool, does it have predictive power? The empirical evidence is mixed. It certainly does not completely explain legislator behavior. There is strong evidence that legislators consider their own ideology, and that of their core constituency, when they vote on policies.

23 Lobbying The issues of money and information make it likely that elected officials will be lobbied by highly interested and informed subgroups. Lobbying is the expending of resources by certain individuals or groups in an attempt to influence a politician. Lobbyists can: Inform politicians Reward politicians The problem with lobbying arises when an issue benefits a small group and imposes small costs on a larger (perhaps even a majority) group. In this case, politicians might support socially inefficient positions. Large groups of people with small individual interest on an issue suffer from a free rider problem in trying to organize politically. Small groups with large interest overcome the free-rider problem.

24 PUBLIC CHOICE THEORY: THE FOUNDATIONS OF GOVERNMENT FAILURE
The analysis in most of this course assumes a benign government intent on maximizing social welfare. Public choice theory questions this assumption by noting that governments often do not behave in an ideal manner, so that traditional assumption of a benevolent social-welfare maximizing government may be inappropriate. Government failure is the inability or unwillingness of the government to act primarily in the interest of its citizens. Reasons include: Size maximizing bureaucracy Leviathan theory Corruption

25 Size-Maximizing Bureaucracy
Niskanen (1971) developed a model of the budget maximizing bureaucrat. In this model, the bureaucrat runs an agency that has a monopoly on the government provision of some good or service. The Bureaucrat’s salary is sometimes unrelated to efficiency. His compensation may consist of salary, but also perks like the size of his office and support staff. The larger government tries to rein in the bureaucrat.

26 Leviathan Theory Leviathan theory sees individual bureaucrats and the larger government as one monopolist that simply tries to maximize the size of the public sector. This view would help explain rules that explicitly tie the government’s hands in terms of taxes and spending.

27 Corruption Finally, corruption is where government officials abuse their power in order to maximize their own personal wealth or that of their associates.

28 The Implications of Government Failure
There is clear evidence that governments fail in some instances to benevolently serve the interests of their citizens. Can citizens “undo” these harms through actions like direct democracy? There is some evidence that more “open” and more well-funded governments have less corruption. Some evidence suggests that government failures can have long-lasting negative impacts on economic growth.


Download ppt "Chapter 9: Political Economy"

Similar presentations


Ads by Google