Download presentation
1
The Factor-Proportions Model
International Trade – Session 3 Daniel TRAÇA
2
Last session In countries with lower productivity, competitiveness in world markets arises from lower wages. The gains from trade mean potential gains for workers. The political argument is due to adjustment costs (specific factors) Factors that are specific to import-competing industries will loose out from trade. Those that are specific to exporting industries will be winners. But the gains of winners always outweigh the loses of losers. Compensating losers is a difficult task!
3
Incomplete specialization I The equilibrium with constant returns
In each sector, workers must be hired until the marginal worker’s cost (the wage) is equal to its marginal product. Workers must be indifferent between the two sectors w = MPLF = MPLM x P Recall that P is the relative price of manufactures In autarky, the price must equate the relative marginal product, to ensure both goods are produced. If the trade price (of manufactures) is lower than in autarky, the country will specialize completely in Agro/Food w total labor force MPLM x PAUT MPLF MPLM x PTRADE LF LM
4
Incomplete specialization II The equilibrium with decreasing returns
Once again, the equilibrium entails w = MPLF = MPLM x P For any given price (P), we can find out the employment and output of Agro/Food and Manufactures. If the trade price (of manufactures) is lower than in autarky, the country will specialize, but not completely, in Agro/Food w total labor force MPLF MPLM x PAUT MPLM x PTRADE LF LM
5
Incomplete specialization III Decreasing returns and the concavity of the PPF
We can obtain the PPF, for the case of decreasing returns. The PPF is concave. The opportunity cost of Food is now increasing. Equilibrium: P = MPLF/MPLM For any price (P), we can obtain the Relative Supply of Manuf. Food Manuf -1/P +1 -1 Slope = -MPLM / MPLF -6 +1
6
Incomplete specialization III The gains from trade in the North
The prices of manufactures rises in the North, Due to its comparative advantage in manufacturing Production of manufactures for export increases; Effects on consumption of manufactures depend on income (+) and substitution effect. But there is incomplete specialization, The North still produces some Food for its own consumption Food Manuf -1/Pw -1/PN Exports Gains from trade Imports
7
The Hecksher-Ohlin (HO) model
2 sectors: Manuf and Food 2 factors: Capital (K) and Labor (L) Factors can freely move between Manuf and Food. This mobility captures long term (no adjustment costs) 2 countries: North(N) and South (S); Differ in relative abundance of Capital and Labor
8
The substitutability of factors
ISOQUANT: combinations of inputs that produce the same quantity of the good The Kapital/Labor ratio (K/L) used in production depends on the prices of the factors. T w/r FF Food w/r K/L L
9
The substitutability of factors
Manuf is a Capital Intensive sector. It uses a higher ratio of K/L, for any given factor prices. ISOQUANT: combinations of inputs that produce the same quantity of the good K w/r FF MM Manuf Food w/r1 K/L L
10
Concavity of the PPF With two factors, and different factor intensities the PPF is concave similarly to decreasing returns For any price, there is incomplete specialization P1 >P2 Food Manuf -1/P1 -1/P2
11
Prices and the real factor-returns - An intuitive scheme
A rise in the relative price of Manuf (P) Food output falls; Manuf output expands Food output decline releases too much Labor (excess supply) Manuf expansion requires mostly Kapital (excess demand) Real wage must fall due to excess demand Kapital rents must rise due to excess supply All sectors become more labor intensive. Full employment of Kapital and Labor is preserved.
12
The factor-price ratio (w/r) and the relative price of manufacture (P)
What is the effect of a rise in P on w/r? An increase in the price of a good raises the relative factor-price of the factor that is used intensively in that sector. e.g. an increase in the relative price of Manuf (Kapital intensive) lower the relative price of labor (w/r) w/r SS P
13
Prices, relative factor returns and factor intensities
w/r MM FF w/r2 w/r1 SS K/L K/LM2 K/LM1 K/LF2 K/LF1 P2 P1 P For any given relative price of goods, there is an equilibrium relative factor price and a given distribution of factor intensities in production. This is independent of the abundance of resources in the economy.
14
An interesting theorem (Rybczinsky)
An increase in Abundance of Kapital The PPF becomes larger, but the change is not parallel: Since Manuf is the main user of Kapital, the difference is relatively larger in Manuf. For the same price, the output of Manuf rises and that of Food declines Manuf F2 M2 M1 F1 Food
15
An interesting theorem (Rybczinsky)
An increase in the supply of a factor, with prices unchanged, raises the output of sectors that use intensively that factor and lowers the output of sectors that do not use intensively A rise in L lowers K/L (right-hand side). With given prices, factor intensities (in square brackets) do not change. Since K/LF < K/LM , employment in Food (LF/L) must rise, and in Manuf (LM/L) must fall. Since LM falls and TM= [T/LM]xLM falls, the production of Manuf must fall
16
The effects of international trade demand
P If the North has more Capital, the relative supply of Manuf is higher than in the South. Use the Rybczinsky theorem The autarky price of Manuf (P) is higher in the South. This means that the South has the Comparative Advantage in Food. With trade, relative price of Manuf rises in the North Comparative Advantage arises because the South is relatively LABOR ABUNDANT and has Comparative Advantage in the LABOR INTENSIVE sectors. RSS RSW RSN PS PW PN RD is the same for both countries and for the World, as a whole. Manuf/Food
17
Resource Abundance, Comparative Advantage and the Pattern of Trade
If technologies are identical, a country has comparative advantage in the sectors that use relatively INTENSIVELY the factors that are relatively ABUNDANT. SOUTH Relatively Labor Abundant Specializes in Food Kapital Intensive MANUF Labor Intensive FOOD NORTH Kapital Abundant Specializes in Manuf
18
Dynamic Comparative Advantage - Accumulating Skills and Capital
Knowledge & R&D Knowledge Intensive (Aeronautics) Skilled Labor Skilled labor Intensive (Electronics) Education, Investment, Infrastructure Economic Development Capital Capital Intensive (Machinery) Labor Unskilled Unskilled labor Intensive (Textiles) Resource Intensive (Rice, Oil) Natural Resources
19
Prices and real factor returns
w/r FF MM w/r1 w/r2 SS K/L K/LM1 K/LM2 K/LF1 K/LF2 P1 P2 P All else constant, a higher relative price of a good… … means a higher relative factor-price of the factor used intensively in that good … and a lower intensity in that factor in both sectors. This has implications for real factor returns: Factor intensity Marginal Product Factor returns
20
Factor returns: Prices vs. Factor abundance
The HO model establishes a unique relationship between goods’ prices and factor prices. The Stolper-Samuelson theorem An increase in the relative price of the good raises the real return to the factor used intensively, and lowers the relative return to the factor not used intensively Changes in P causes lower in K/LM and K/LF,… …raising the return to capital and lowering the wage In this context, if goods prices are constant, an increase in the abundance of a given factor does not affect factor returns, it simply affects the relative output of the goods (remember the Rybczinsky effect)
21
Factor abundance and factor prices in autarky
Comparing Real Factor Returns in the North, with the South Due to higher Kapital abundance, the North has comparative advantage in K-intensive goods (Manuf). The autarky relative-price of Manuf is lower in the North, than in the South. Kapital intensity in Manuf and Food is higher in the North, than in the South. This is necessary to ensure that the higher abundance of Kapital is used up. Real (Labor) Wages are higher and (Kapital) Rents are lower in the North, than in the South.
22
Unfair Competition If the items entering this country in such volumes were better designed or more attractive, more durable or more efficiently produced, we would have little reason to object. But the vast majority of imports sell here primarily because they are cheaper; and they are cheaper for one reason only - they are made at wages and under working conditions that would be illegal and intolerable in this country’. from the President of American Textile Manufacturers Institute Good working conditions High unskilled wages Low returns for unskilled labor High returns for unskilled labor Abundance in unskilled labor Abundance in skilled labor and capital Rich countries Poor countries Poor working conditions Low unskilled wages
23
Unfair Competition and Comparative Advantage
Low wage competition is comparative advantage in goods that are intensive in educated/skill labor for industrialized countries Trade creates value because returns to unskilled workers are lower in developing countries The mix between wages and working conditions is mostly market driven. Legal constraints have a cost that depends on how restrictive they are, relative to market outcomes. Part of this cost is borne by workers in the form of unemployment and lower net wages. It is a cost that rich, industrialized societies have accepted to pay to promote social justice and avoid exploitation.
24
Summary Comparative Advantage (and gains from trade) may arise from differences in the relative abundance of factors, if they are used with different intensities across sectors Comparative advantage in sectors the used intensively the abundant factor. Changes in factor abundance due to economic development will affect the country’s comparative advantage. Low wages in poor countries are due, in part, to low capital abundance. These low wages are the source of gains from trade and not unfair competition
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.