Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
1
© 2010 Pearson Education
2
In some markets, there are only a few firms compete. For example, computer chips are made by Intel and Advanced Micro Devices and each firm must pay close attention to what the other firm is doing. How does competition between just two chip makers work? When a market has only a small number of firms, do they operate in the social interest, like firms in perfect competition? Or do they restrict output to increase profit, like a monopoly? The models of perfect competition and monopoly don’t predict the behavior of the firms we’ve just described. To understand how these markets work, we need the richer models.
3
© 2010 Pearson Education What Is Oligopoly? Oligopoly is a market structure in which Natural or legal barriers prevent the entry of new firms. A small number of firms compete.
4
© 2010 Pearson Education Barriers to Entry Either natural or legal barriers to entry can create oligopoly. Figure 15.1 shows two oligopoly situations. In part (a), there is a natural duopoly—a market with two firms. What Is Oligopoly?
5
© 2010 Pearson Education
6
In part (b), there is a natural oligopoly market with three firms. A legal oligopoly might arise even where the demand and costs leave room for a larger number of firms. What Is Oligopoly?
7
© 2010 Pearson Education
8
Small Number of Firms Because an oligopoly market has a small number of firms, the firms are interdependent and face a temptation to cooperate. Interdependence: With a small number of firms, each firm’s profit depends on every firm’s actions. Cartel: A cartel and is an illegal group of firms acting together to limit output, raise price, and increase profit. Firms in oligopoly face the temptation to form a cartel, but aside from being illegal, cartels often break down. What Is Oligopoly?
9
© 2010 Pearson Education Two Traditional Oligopoly Models The Kinked Demand Curve Model In the kinked demand curve model of oligopoly, each firm believes that if it raises its price, its competitors will not follow, but if it lowers its price all of its competitors will follow.
10
© 2010 Pearson Education Figure 15.2 shows the kinked demand curve model. The firm believes that the demand for its product has a kink at the current price and quantity. Two Traditional Oligopoly Models
11
© 2010 Pearson Education
12
Above the kink, demand is relatively elastic because all other firm’s prices remain unchanged. Below the kink, demand is relatively inelastic because all other firm’s prices change in line with the price of the firm shown in the figure. Two Traditional Oligopoly Models
13
© 2010 Pearson Education The kink in the demand curve means that the MR curve is discontinuous at the current quantity—shown by that gap AB in the figure. Two Traditional Oligopoly Models
14
© 2010 Pearson Education This slide helps to envisage why the kink in the demand curve puts a break in the marginal revenue curve. Two Traditional Oligopoly Models
15
© 2010 Pearson Education
16
Fluctuations in MC that remain within the discontinuous portion of the MR curve leave the profit- maximizing quantity and price unchanged. For example, if costs increased so that the MC curve shifted upward from MC 0 to MC 1, the profit- maximizing price and quantity would not change. Two Traditional Oligopoly Models
17
© 2010 Pearson Education The beliefs that generate the kinked demand curve are not always correct and firms can figure out this fact. If MC increases enough, all firms raise their prices and the kink vanishes. A firm that bases its actions on wrong beliefs doesn’t maximize profit. Two Traditional Oligopoly Models
18
© 2010 Pearson Education Dominant Firm Oligopoly In a dominant firm oligopoly, there is one large firm that has a significant cost advantage over many other, smaller competing firms. The large firm operates as a monopoly, setting its price and output to maximize its profit. The small firms act as perfect competitors, taking as given the market price set by the dominant firm. Two Traditional Oligopoly Models
19
© 2010 Pearson Education Figure 15.3 shows10 small firms in part (a). The demand curve, D, is the market demand and the supply curve S 10 is the supply of the 10 small firms. Two Traditional Oligopoly Models
20
© 2010 Pearson Education
21
At a price of $1.50, the 10 small firms produce the quantity demanded. At this price, the large firm would sell nothing. Two Traditional Oligopoly Models
22
© 2010 Pearson Education But if the price was $1.00, the 10 small firms would supply only half the market, leaving the rest to the large firm. Two Traditional Oligopoly Models
23
© 2010 Pearson Education The demand curve for the large firm’s output is the curve XD on the right. Two Traditional Oligopoly Models
24
© 2010 Pearson Education The large firm can set the price and receives a marginal revenue that is less than price along the curve MR. Two Traditional Oligopoly Models
25
© 2010 Pearson Education The large firm maximizes profit by setting MR = MC. Let’s suppose that the marginal cost curve is MC in the figure. Two Traditional Oligopoly Models
26
© 2010 Pearson Education The profit-maximizing quantity for the large firm is 10 units. The price charged is $1.00. Two Traditional Oligopoly Models
27
© 2010 Pearson Education The small firms take this price and supply the rest of the quantity demanded. Two Traditional Oligopoly Models
28
© 2010 Pearson Education In the long run, such an industry might become a monopoly as the large firm buys up the small firms and cuts costs. Two Traditional Oligopoly Models
29
© 2010 Pearson Education Oligopoly Games Game theory is a tool for studying strategic behavior, which is behavior that takes into account the expected behavior of others and the mutual recognition of interdependence. The Prisoners’ Dilemma The prisoners’ dilemma game illustrates the four features of a game. Rules Strategies Payoffs Outcome
30
© 2010 Pearson Education Rules The rules describe the setting of the game, the actions the players may take, and the consequences of those actions. In the prisoners’ dilemma game, two prisoners (Art and Bob) have been caught committing a petty crime. Each is held in a separate cell and cannot communicate with each other. Oligopoly Games
31
© 2010 Pearson Education Each is told that both are suspected of committing a more serious crime. If one of them confesses, he will get a 1-year sentence for cooperating while his accomplice get a 10-year sentence for both crimes. If both confess to the more serious crime, each receives 3 years in jail for both crimes. If neither confesses, each receives a 2-year sentence for the minor crime only. Oligopoly Games
32
© 2010 Pearson Education Strategies Strategies are all the possible actions of each player. Art and Bob each have two possible actions: 1. Confess to the larger crime. 2. Deny having committed the larger crime. With two players and two actions for each player, there are four possible outcomes: 1. Both confess. 2. Both deny. 3. Art confesses and Bob denies. 4. Bob confesses and Art denies. Oligopoly Games
33
© 2010 Pearson Education Payoffs Each prisoner can work out what happens to him—can work out his payoff—in each of the four possible outcomes. We can tabulate these outcomes in a payoff matrix. A payoff matrix is a table that shows the payoffs for every possible action by each player for every possible action by the other player. The next slide shows the payoff matrix for this prisoners’ dilemma game. Oligopoly Games
34
© 2010 Pearson Education Oligopoly Games
35
© 2010 Pearson Education Outcome If a player makes a rational choice in pursuit of his own best interest, he chooses the action that is best for him, given any action taken by the other player. If both players are rational and choose their actions in this way, the outcome is an equilibrium called Nash equilibrium—first proposed by John Nash. Finding the Nash Equilibrium The following slides show how to find the Nash equilibrium. Oligopoly Games
36
© 2010 Pearson Education Bob’s view of the world
37
© 2010 Pearson Education Bob’s view of the world
38
© 2010 Pearson Education Art’s view of the world
39
© 2010 Pearson Education Art’s view of the world
40
© 2010 Pearson Education Equilibrium
41
© 2010 Pearson Education An Oligopoly Price-Fixing Game A game like the prisoners’ dilemma is played in duopoly. A duopoly is a market in which there are only two producers that compete. Duopoly captures the essence of oligopoly. Cost and Demand Conditions Figure 15.4 on the next slide describes the cost and demand situation in a natural duopoly. Oligopoly Games
42
© 2010 Pearson Education Part (a) shows each firm’s cost curves. Part (b) shows the market demand curve. Oligopoly Games
43
© 2010 Pearson Education
44
This industry is a natural duopoly. Two firms can meet the market demand at the least cost. Oligopoly Games
45
© 2010 Pearson Education How does this market work? What is the price and quantity produced in equilibrium? Oligopoly Games
46
© 2010 Pearson Education Collusion Suppose that the two firms enter into a collusive agreement. A collusive agreement is an agreement between two (or more) firms to restrict output, raise the price, and increase profits. Such agreements are illegal in the United States and are undertaken in secret. Firms in a collusive agreement operate a cartel. Oligopoly Games
47
© 2010 Pearson Education The strategies that firms in a cartel can pursue are to Comply Cheat Because each firm has two strategies, there are four possible combinations of actions for the firms: 1. Both comply. 2. Both cheat. 3. Trick complies and Gear cheats. 4. Gear complies and Trick cheats. Oligopoly Games
48
© 2010 Pearson Education Colluding to Maximize Profits Firms in a cartel act like a monopoly and maximum economic profit. Oligopoly Games
49
© 2010 Pearson Education
50
To find that profit, we set marginal cost for the cartel equal to marginal revenue for the cartel. Oligopoly Games
51
© 2010 Pearson Education The cartel’s marginal cost curve is the horizontal sum of the MC curves of the two firms and the marginal revenue curve is like that of a monopoly. Oligopoly Games
52
© 2010 Pearson Education The firm’s maximize economic profit by producing the quantity at which MC I = MR. Oligopoly Games
53
© 2010 Pearson Education Each firm agrees to produce 2,000 units and each firm shares the maximum economic profit. The blue rectangle shows each firm’s economic profit. Oligopoly Games
54
© 2010 Pearson Education When each firm produces 2,000 units, the price is greater than the firm’s marginal cost, so if one firm increased output, its profit would increase. Oligopoly Games
55
© 2010 Pearson Education One Firm Cheats on a Collusive Agreement Suppose the cheat increases its output to 3,000 units. Industry output increases to 5,000 and the price falls. Oligopoly Games
56
© 2010 Pearson Education
57
For the complier, ATC now exceeds price. For the cheat, price exceeds ATC. Oligopoly Games
58
© 2010 Pearson Education The complier incurs an economic loss. The cheat makes an increased economic profit. Oligopoly Games
59
© 2010 Pearson Education Both Firms Cheat Suppose that both increase their output to 3,000 units. Oligopoly Games
60
© 2010 Pearson Education
61
Industry output is 6,000 units, the price falls, and both firms make zero economic profit—the same as in perfect competition. Oligopoly Games
62
© 2010 Pearson Education Possible Outcomes If both comply, each firm makes $2 million a week. If both cheat, each firm makes zero economic profit. If Trick complies and Gear cheats, Trick incurs an economic loss of $1 million and Gear makes an economic profit of $4.5 million. If Gear complies and Trick cheats, Gear incurs an economic loss of $1 million and Trick makes an economic profit of $4.5 million. The next slide shows the payoff matrix for the duopoly game. Oligopoly Games
63
© 2010 Pearson Education Payoff Matrix
64
© 2010 Pearson Education Trick’s view of the world
65
© 2010 Pearson Education Trick’s view of the world
66
© 2010 Pearson Education Gear’s view of the world
67
© 2010 Pearson Education Gear’s view of the world
68
© 2010 Pearson Education Equilibrium
69
© 2010 Pearson Education Nash Equilibrium in Duopolists’ Dilemma The Nash equilibrium is that both firms cheat. The quantity and price are those of a competitive market, and the firms make zero economic profit. Other Oligopoly Games Advertising and R&D games are also prisoners’ dilemmas. An R&D Game Procter & Gamble and Kimberley Clark play an R&D game in the market for disposable diapers. Oligopoly Games
70
© 2010 Pearson Education The payoff matrix for the Pampers Versus Huggies game. Oligopoly Games
71
© 2010 Pearson Education The Disappearing Invisible Hand In all the versions of the prisoners’ dilemma that we’ve examined, the players end up worse off than they would if they were able to cooperate. The pursuit of self-interest does not promote the social interest in these games. Oligopoly Games
72
© 2010 Pearson Education A Game of Chicken In the prisoners’ dilemma game, the Nash equilibrium is a dominant strategy equilibrium, by which we mean the best strategy for each player is independent of what the other player does. Not all games have such an equilibrium. One that doesn’t is the game of “chicken.” Oligopoly Games
73
© 2010 Pearson Education Payoff Matrix
74
© 2010 Pearson Education KC’s view of the world
75
© 2010 Pearson Education KC’s view of the world
76
© 2010 Pearson Education P&G’s view of the world
77
© 2010 Pearson Education P&G’s view of the world
78
© 2010 Pearson Education Equilibrium
79
© 2010 Pearson Education Repeated Games and Sequential Games A Repeated Duopoly Game If a game is played repeatedly, it is possible for duopolists to successfully collude and make a monopoly profit. If the players take turns and move sequentially (rather than simultaneously as in the prisoner’s dilemma), many outcomes are possible. In a repeated prisoners’ dilemma duopoly game, additional punishment strategies enable the firms to comply and achieve a cooperative equilibrium, in which the firms make and share the monopoly profit.
80
© 2010 Pearson Education One possible punishment strategy is a tit-for-tat strategy. A tit-for-tat strategy is one in which one player cooperates this period if the other player cooperated in the previous period but cheats in the current period if the other player cheated in the previous period. A more severe punishment strategy is a trigger strategy. A trigger strategy is one in which a player cooperates if the other player cooperates but plays the Nash equilibrium strategy forever thereafter if the other player cheats. Repeated Games and Sequential Games
81
© 2010 Pearson Education Table 15.5 shows that a tit-for-tat strategy is sufficient to produce a cooperative equilibrium in a repeated duopoly game. Repeated Games and Sequential Games
82
© 2010 Pearson Education
83
Price wars might result from a tit-for-tat strategy where there is an additional complication—uncertainty about changes in demand. A fall in demand might lower the price and bring forth a round of tit-for-tat punishment. Repeated Games and Sequential Games
84
© 2010 Pearson Education A Sequential Entry Game in a Contestable Market In a contestable market—a market in which firms can enter and leave so easily that firms in the market face competition from potential entrants—firms play a sequential entry game. Repeated Games and Sequential Games
85
© 2010 Pearson Education Figure 15.8 shows the game tree for a sequential entry game in a contestable market. Repeated Games and Sequential Games
86
© 2010 Pearson Education
87
In the first stage, Agile decides whether to set the monopoly price or the competitive price. Repeated Games and Sequential Games
88
© 2010 Pearson Education In the second stage, Wanabe decides whether to enter or stay out. Repeated Games and Sequential Games
89
© 2010 Pearson Education In the equilibrium of this entry game, Agile sets a competitive price and makes zero economic profit to keep Wanabe out. A less costly strategy is limit pricing, which sets the price at the highest level that is consistent with keeping the potential entrant out. Repeated Games and Sequential Games
90
© 2010 Pearson Education Antitrust Law Antitrust law provides an alternative way in which the government may influence the marketplace. The Antitrust Laws The first antitrust law, the Sherman Act, was passed in 1890. It outlawed any “combination, trust, or conspiracy that restricts interstate trade,” and prohibited the “attempt to monopolize.”
91
© 2010 Pearson Education Antitrust Law
92
© 2010 Pearson Education A wave of merger activities at the beginning of the twentieth century produced a stronger antitrust law, the Clayton Act, and created the Federal Trade Commission. The Clayton Act was passed in 1914. The Clayton Act made illegal specific business practices such as price discrimination, interlocking directorships, and acquisition of a competitor’s shares if the practices “substantially lessen competition or create monopoly.” Antitrust Law
93
© 2010 Pearson Education Table 15.7 (next slide) summarizes the Clayton Act and its amendments, the Robinson-Patman Act passed in 1936 and the Cellar-Kefauver Act passed in 1950. The Federal Trade Commission, formed in 1914, looks for cases of “unfair methods of competition and unfair or deceptive business practices.” Antitrust Law
94
© 2010 Pearson Education Antitrust Law
95
© 2010 Pearson Education Price Fixing Always Illegal Price fixing is always a violation of the antitrust law. If the Justice Department can prove the existence of price fixing, there is no defense. Antitrust Law
96
© 2010 Pearson Education Three Antitrust Policy Debates But some practices are more controversial and generate debate. Three of them are Resale price maintenance Tying arrangements Predatory pricing Antitrust Law
97
© 2010 Pearson Education Resale Price Maintenance Most manufacturers sell their product to the final consumer through a wholesale and retail distribution chain. Resale price maintenance occurs when a manufacturer agrees with a distributor on the price at which the product will be resold. Resale price maintenance is inefficient if it promotes monopoly pricing. But resale price maintenance can be efficient if it provides retailers with an incentive to provide an efficient level of retail service in selling a product. Antitrust Law
98
© 2010 Pearson Education Tying Arrangements A tying arrangement is an agreement to sell one product only if the buyer agrees to buy another different product as well. Some people argue that by tying, a firm can make a larger profit. Where buyers have a differing willingness to pay for the separate items, a firm can price discriminate and take a larger amount of the consumer surplus by tying. Antitrust Law
99
© 2010 Pearson Education Predatory Pricing Predatory pricing is setting a low price to drive competitors out of business with the intention of then setting the monopoly price. Economists are skeptical that predatory pricing actually occurs. A high, certain, and immediate loss is a poor exchange for a temporary, uncertain, and future gain. No case of predatory pricing has been definitively found. Antitrust Law
100
© 2010 Pearson Education Merger Rules The Federal Trade Commission (FTC) uses guidelines to determine which mergers to examine and possibly block. The Herfindahl-Hirschman index (HHI) is one of those guidelines (explained in Chapter 9). If the original HHI is between 1,000 and 1,800, any merger that raises the HHI by 100 or more is challenged. If the original HHI is greater than 1,800, any merger that raises the HHI by more than 50 is challenged. Antitrust Law
Similar presentations
© 2024 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.