Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
1
FIN 645: International Financial Management
Lecture 3 International Parity Relationships & Forecasting Exchange Rates
2
Long and Short Forward Positions
One can buy (take a long position) or sell (take a short position) foreign exchange forward A speculative forward position $ will likely appreciate in value against the Swiss Franc The trader will short the three-month $/SF contract on January 4,2008 at F3 = $0.9077 Assume (S)he sells SF 5,000,000 forward against dollars On April 4, S($/SF) = $0.9007 The trader can buy Swiss Franc spot at $ and deliver it under the forward contract at a price of $0.9077 Speculative profit($ $0.9007) =$0.0070 Total profit from the trade $35000 = (SF 5,000,000x$0.0070) What if the $ depreciated and S3 = $0.9107? Graph of long and short position The speculator would have lost ($ $0.9107)= - $ per unit for a total loss of -$15,000=(SF5,000,000)(- $ ).
3
Graph of Long and Short Forward Positions
Profit(+) F3($/SF) Long position .0070 .9107 S3=($/SF) .9007 F3($/SF)= .9077 -.0030 Short position -F3($/SF) Loss
4
Lecture Outline Forces Driving Exchange Rate Changes
Interest Rate Parity (IRP) Covered Interest Arbitrage IRP and Exchange Rate Determination Reasons for Deviations from IRP The Law of One Price The two things that are equal to each other must be selling for the same price Forecasting Foreign Exchange Rates? How are Foreign Exchange Rates Determined? The law of one price prevails when the same or equivalent things are trading at the same price across different locations or markets, precluding arbitrage opportunities. Interest rate parity, IRP states that the forward premium or discount between two currencies is determined by the nominal interest rate differential between those currencies. According to IRP, the currency of the country with a lower interest rate should be at a forward premium in terms of currency of the country with the higher rate When IRP does not hold, the situation gives rise to covered interest arbitrage opportunities.
5
Lecture Outline Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) The Fisher Effect
PPP Deviations and the Real Exchange Rate Evidence on PPP The Fisher Effect Forecasting Exchange Rates Efficient Market Approach Fundamental Approach Technical Approach Performance of the Forecasters PPP states that exchange rate between currencies of two countries should be equal to the ratio of the countries’ price level Fisher effect holds that an increase (decrease) in the expected inflation rate in a country will cause a proportionate increase (decrease) in the interest rate in the country.
6
Arbitrage Equilibrium
The term Arbitrage can be defined as the act of buying and selling the same or equivalent assets or commodities for the purpose of making certain guaranteed profit. As long as there are profitable arbitrage opportunities, the market cannot be in equilibrium The market is said to be in equilibrium when no profitable arbitrage opportunities exist Parity relationships such as IRP and PPP, in fact, represent arbitrage equilibrium condition
7
Interest Rate Parity Defined
IRP is an arbitrage condition that must hold when international financial markets are in equilibrium. If IRP did not hold, then it would be possible for an astute trader to make unlimited amounts of money exploiting the arbitrage opportunity. Since we don’t typically observe persistent arbitrage conditions, we can safely assume that IRP holds. Interest rate parity, IRP states that the forward premium or discount between two currencies is determined by the nominal interest rate differential between those currencies. According to IRP, the currency of the country with a lower interest rate should be at a forward premium in terms of currency of the country with the higher rate
8
Interest Rate Parity Defined
Suppose you have $ 1 to invest for 1 yr. You can either invest in the U.S. at i$, receive future maturity value = $1 (1 + i$); or exchange your dollars for pound at the spot rate (S), get £(1/S), invest in the U.K. at interest rate i£ , with the maturity value of £(1/S) (1 + i£). hedge your exchange rate risk by selling the future value of the U.K investment forward (for a predetermined dollar amount). The future value = $[(1/S)(1 + i£)] F, where F denotes the forward exchange rate. Assumption, default free investments like a U.S. Treasury note S (Spot) and F (Forward) rates represent dollar price of one unit of foreign currency- direct quotation from US perspective. We leave out the subscripts £= $1.60
9
Interest Rate Parity Defined
Please note that when your British investment matures in one year, you will receive the full maturity value, £(1/S) (1 + i£). But you have to deliver exactly the same amount of pounds to the counterparty of the forward contract, your net pound position is reduced to zero. In other words, the exchange risk is completely hedged You have effectively denominated the UK investment in dollar terms Since both of these investments have the same risk, they must have the same future value—otherwise an arbitrage opportunity would exist. (F/S)(1 + i£) = (1 + i$) The “effective” dollar interest rate from the U.K. investment alternative is: (F/S)(1 + i£)-1
10
Interest Rate Parity Defined
Formally, (F/S)(1 + i£) = (1 + i$) or if you prefer, IRP is sometimes approximated as IRP provides a linkage between interest rates in two different countries. From the third equation it is clear that the interest rate will be higher in the US than in the U.K.when the dollar is at a forward discount., i.e. F>S, i.e. dollar is expected to depreciate against the pound. This is necessary to compensate for the expected depreciation of the dollar. The opposite, interest rate will be lower in the US than in the U.K. when the dollar is at a forward premium, i.e. F<S. The equation also indicates that the forward exchange rate will deviate from the spot rate as long as the interest rates of the two countries are not the same. When IRP holds, one will be indifferent between investing the money the US or Japan with forward hedging. However, if IRP is violated you will prefer one to another. When IRP does not hold, the situation gives rise to covered interest arbitrage opportunities. Note that Forward and Spot rates are defined as the dollar price of one unit of FX IRP is a manifestation of the law of one price (LOP) to international money market instruments.
11
Alternative Derivation IRP
IRP can also be derived by constructing an arbitrage portfolio, which involves (i) no net investment; (ii) no risk, and then requiring that such a portfolio should not generate any net cash flow in equilibrium Consider an arbitrage portfolio consisting of three separate positions: Borrow $S in the US, which is just enough to buy £1 at the prevailing spot exchange rate (S). Lending £1 in the UK at the UK interest rate Selling the maturity value of the UK investment forward
12
Dollar Cash Flows to An Arbitrage Portfolio
Transactions CF0 CF1 1. Borrow in the U.S. $S -S(1+i$) 2. Lend in the U.K. -$S S1(1+i£) 3. Sell the £ receivable forward* (1+i£)(F-S1) Net cash flow (1+i£)F-(1+i$)S (1+i£)(F-S1)+S1(1+i£)-S(1+i$) =(1+i£)F- S1(1+i£)+ S1(1+i£)-(1+i$)S =(1+i£)F-(1+i$)S Selling the £ receivable “forward” will not result in any cash flow at the present time, that is, CF0=0. But at the maturity, the seller will receive $(F-S1) for each pound sold forward. S1 denotes the future spot exchange rate.
13
Dollar Cash Flows to An Arbitrage Portfolio
Note that: The Net cash flow at the time of investment is zero; i.e. the arbitrage portfolio is self financing; it does not cost any money to hold this portfolio; The net cash flow on the maturity date is known with certainty, because S,F, i£, and i$ are all known. Since no one should be able to make certain profits by holding this arbitrage portfolio, market equilibrium requires that the net cash flow on the maturity date be zero for this portfolio: (1+i£)F-(1+i$)S=0 By rearrangement, we have: (F/S)(1 + i£) = (1 + i$)
14
IRP and Interest Rates The IRP relationship is often approximated by:
(i$- i£) = (F-S)/S From the above relationship, it can be seen that IRP provides a relationship between interest rate of two countries. Interest rate will be higher in the US than in the UK when the dollar is at a forward discount, i.e. F>S Interest rate will be higher in the UK than in the US when the dollar is at a forward premium, i.e. F<S Forward exchange rate will deviate from the spot rate as long as the interest rates of the two countries are not the same. The exact version is: (i$- i£) = (F-S)/S(1+ i£) Recall that S and F represents dollar price of 1 unit of foreign currency. When the dollar is at a forward discount, this implies that dollar is expected to depreciate against the pound. If so, the US interest rate should be higher than the U.K. interest rate to compensate for the expected depreciation of dollar. Otherwise, no one will hold dollar-denominated securities
15
Covered Interest Arbitrage
When IRP holds, you will be indifferent between investing your money in the US and investing in the UK with forward hedging. If IRP is violated, you will be better off by investing in the US(U.K) if (1 + i$) is greater (less) than (F/S)(1 + i£). On the other hand, if you need to borrow, you will choose to borrow where the dollar interest rate is lower. When IRP does not hold, the situation gives rise to covered interest arbitrage opportunities
16
Covered Interest Arbitrage: Cash Flow Analysis
Transactions CF0 CF1 1. Borrow $1,000,000 $1,000,000 -$1,050,000 2. Buy £ spot -$1,000,000 £666,667 3. Lend £666,667 -£666,667 £720,000 4. Sell 720,000 forward $1,065,600 Net cash flow $ 15,600 i$=5%, i£=8%, S=$1.5, F = $1.48 First check whether IRP holds (F/S)(1 + i£) =1.5/1.48(1.08) = ≠ (1 + i$) =1.05 i.e. (F/S)(1 + i£) > (1 + i$) Clearly, IRP is not holding, implying that a profitable arbitrage opportunity exists. In the US, borrow $1,000,000. Repayment in one year will be $1,000,000x1.05 = $1,050,000 Buy £666,667 spot using $1,000,000 Invest £666,667 in the UK, the maturity value will be £666,667x1.08 = £720,000 Sell £720,000 forward (£720,000)*($1.48/ £)=$1,065,600 Arbitrage profit = $ 15,600 Arbitrage profit is equal to the effective interest differential times the amount borrowed ( )x1,000,000 = 15,500
17
Interest Rate Parity Diagram
(F-S)/S (%) IRP line 4 3 2 B 1 -4 -3 -2 -1 1 2 3 4 (i$-i£)(%) Initial market condition is represented by point A substantially off the IRP line. At point A, the interest rate differential is -3%, i$-i£= (5%-8%), the forward premium is -1.33%, i.e. (F-S)/S = ( )/1.5= , or -1.33%. CIA activities will increase the interest rate differential (as indicated by the horizontal arrow) and, at the same time, lower forward premium/discount (as indicated by the vertical arrow), Both the foreign exchange and the money markets share the burden of adjustments, the actual path of adjustment is indicated by the dotted arrow. At point B, IRP will be restored partly by an increase in the forward premium, (F-S)/S, and partly by decrease in the interest rate differential, i$-i£. -1 A -2 -3 -4
18
Another CIA Example Three month interest rate in the US: 8.0% per annum Three month interest rate in Germany: 5.0% per annum Current spot exchange rate: € /$ Three-month forward exchange rate: € /$ Again, we assume that the arbitrager can borrow $1,000,000 or the equivalent € amount, € 1,011,400 Calculate arbitrage profit, if any.
19
Covered Interest Arbitrage: Cash Flow Analysis 2
Transactions CF0 CF1 1. Borrow € 1,011,400 € 1,011,400 - € 1,024,042.50 2. Buy $ spot - € 1,011,400 $1,000,000 3. Lend $1,000,000 -$1,000,000 $1,020,000 4. Buy 1,024, forward -€ 1,024,042.50 $1,013,803 Net cash flow $ 6,197 This example differs from the previous one in the following ways: The transaction horizon here is three-months rather than a year The exchange rates are quoted in European rather than American terms. And therefore, use three-month interest rate, not annualized rates and convert the exchange rates into US dollars. i$=8/4=2%, i€=5/4=1.25%, Current spot exchange rate € =1.0114/$; Three month forward exchange rate exchange rate € =1.0101/$ S=1/1.0114=0.9887, F = 1/1.0101=0.9900 First check whether IRP holds (F/S)(1 + i€) =0.9900/0.9887(1.0125) = ≠ (1 + i$) =1.02, i.e. (F/S)(1 + i£) < (1 + i$) Clearly, IRP is not holding, implying that a profitable arbitrage opportunity exists. In Germany, borrow €1,011,400. Repayment in three-month will be € 1,011,400 x = € 1,024,042.5 Buy $1,000,000 spot using € 1,011,400 Invest $1,000,000 in the US, the maturity value will be $1,000,000x1.02 = $1,020,000 in three months Buy € 1,024,042.5 forward (€ 1,024,042.5 *)/ (€1.0101/ $)=$1,013,803 Arbitrage profit = $ 6,197 Arbitrage profit is equal to the effective interest differential times the amount borrowed.
20
Covered Interest Arbitrage (CIP)
Covered Interest Arbitrage is a situation which occurs when IRP does not hold, thereby allowing certain arbitrage profits to be made without the arbitrageur investing any money out of pocket or bearing any risk. To see if any CIP opportunities exist?, Verify
21
Deviations from IRP and Market Adjustments
How long will the arbitrage opportunity will last? As soon as deviations from IRP are detected, informed traders will carry out CIA transactions Borrow in the US, interest rate in the US will rise (i$ ↑) Lend in the UK, interest rate will fall in the UK(i£↓) Buy the pound spot, the pound will appreciate in the spot market (S↑) Sell the pound forward, the pound will depreciate in the forward market (F↓) These adjustments will raise LHS of IRP equation and lower the RHS until both sides are equalized, restoring IRP Arbitrage opportunity will last for only for a short while
22
IRP and Exchange Rate Determination
IRP relationship can be written as S = [(1 + i£)/(1 + i$)]*F, i.e. given the forward exchange rate, the spot exchange rate depends on the relative interest rates. All else equal, in this example, an increase in the US interest rate will attract capital to the US, increasing demand for dollars and will lead to a lower spot exchange rate -higher foreign exchange value of the dollar. A decrease in the US interest rate will lower foreign exchange value of the dollar. (1+i£)F = (1+i$) S S represents US dollar per pound
23
IRP and Exchange Rate Determination
In addition to the relative interest rates, the forward exchange rate is an important determinant of the spot exchange rate. Under certain conditions, the forward exchange rate can be viewed as the expected future spot exchange rate conditional on all relevant information being available now. F = E(St+1|It) St+1= the future spot rate when the forward contract matures It denotes the set of information currently available: money supply, interest rates, trade balances, and other factors that would influence the exchange rate.
24
IRP and Exchange Rate Determination
S = [(1 + i£)/(1 + i$)]* E(St+1|It) “Expectation” plays a key role in exchange rate determination, i.e. the expected future exchange rate is the major determinant of the current exchange rate. Exchange rate behavior will be driven by news events(It) Self fulfilling prophecy: when people expect exchange rate to go up in the future, it goes up now Dynamic and volatile short term behavior News events are unpredictable, thus making foreign exchange rate forecasting an arduous task.
25
Uncovered Interest Parity
When the forward exchange rate F is replaced by the expected exchange rate, E(St+1), we get the uncovered interest rate parity relationship shown below: (i$- i£) = E(e), where E(e) is the expected rate of change in the exchange rate, i.e. [E(St+1)-St]/St Interest rate differential between a pair of countries is (approximately ) equal to the expected rate of change in the exchange rate. If i$= 5% and i£=8%, the uncovered IRP suggests the the pound is expected to depreciate against the dollar by 3 %, i.e. E(e)=-3%
26
Reasons for Deviations from IRP
Transactions Costs The interest rate available to an arbitrager for borrowing, ib,may exceed the rate he can lend at, il. There may be bid-ask spreads to overcome, Fb/Sa < F/S Thus (Fb/Sa)(1 + i¥l) (1 + i¥ b) 0 Capital Controls Governments sometimes restrict import and export of money through taxes or outright bans. Imposing taxes, or even outright ban on cross-border capital movements Jawboning :The actual economic impact of preventing price increases in response to changes in supply and demand is that businesses are forced to bear the cost of inflation. Among other consequences, this reduces the ability of companies hire new employees since there is already significant pressure on profit margins. Jawboning tends to increase unemployment. In the end, the people who bear the cost of inflation are workers, since they are paid less and some have no work at all.
27
Interest Rate Parity With Transaction Costs
(F-S)/S (%) IRP line 4 3 2 D 1 -4 -3 -2 -1 1 2 3 4 (i$-i£)(%) -1 C Point C would represent profitable arbitrage opportunities but point D would not represent profitable arbitrage opportunities -2 -3 Unprofitable arbitrage -4
28
Deviations from Interest Rate Parity
Empirical evidence Japan imposed capital controls off and on until December 1980 Otani and Tiwari investigated the effect of capital controls on IRP deviations during They compute deviations from IRP DIRP = [(1+i¥)S/(1+i$)F] -1 If IRP strictly holds deviations from it would be randomly distributed, with the expected value of zero. They found that deviations from IRP hardly hover around zero. Highest during 1978(Japan discouraged capital inflows to keep the yen from appreciating). As these were removed deviations decreased in Increased again in 1980, as Japanese financial institutions were asked to reduce FC deposits. In December 1940, Japan liberalized FE transactions, deviations close to zero Deviations from IRP, especially in 1978 and 1980, do not represent unexploited profit opportunities, rather barriers to cross border arbitrage.
29
Purchasing Power Parity
Purchasing Power Parity and Exchange Rate Determination PPP Deviations and the Real Exchange Rate Evidence on PPP
30
Purchasing Power Parity and Exchange Rate Determination
Absolute PPP The exchange rate between two currencies should equal the ratio of the countries’ price levels. S(h/f) = Ph Pf h (home currency) and f (foreign currency); Ph (home price level) Pf (foreign price level) Standard commodity basket in the US is $225, in the UK £150, the exchange rate should be $1.50 per pound. PPP requires that the price of the standard commodity basket be the same across countries when measured in a common currency. Ricardo and Gustav Cassel 1920s; Hyperinflation in Germany, Hungary and Soviet Union, decline in purchasing power of local currency was accompanied by sharp depreciation against stable currencies such as USD. P$=SXP£, the dollar price of the commodity basket in the US, P$, must be the same as the dollar price of the basket in the U.K.i.e. SXP£. PPP requires that the price of the standard commodity basket be the same across countries when measured in a common currency. Manifestation of law of one price. Big Mac
31
“A Feast of Burgernomics”
Big Mac PPP: For example, using figures in July 2008: the price of a Big Mac was $3.57 in the United States the price of a Big Mac was £2.29 in the United Kingdom (Britain) the implied purchasing power parity was $1.56 to £1, that is $3.57/£2.29 = 1.56 this compares with an actual exchange rate of $2.00 to £1 at the time the pound was thus overvalued against the dollar by 28%, i.e. the actual exchange rate divided by implied purchasing parity → 2 divided by 1.56 = 1.28
32
“A Feast of Burgernomics”
The dollar’s recent revival has made fewer currencies look dear against the Big Mac index, our lighthearted guide to exchange rates. The index is based on the idea of purchasing-power parity, which says currencies should trade at the rate that makes the price of goods the same in each country. So if the price of a Big Mac translated into dollars is above $3.54, its cost in America, the currency is dear; if it is below that benchmark, it is cheap. There are three noteworthy shifts since the summer. The yen, which had looked very cheap, is now close to fair value. So is the pound, which had looked dear the last time we compared burger prices in July. The euro is still overvalued on the burger gauge, but far less so than last summer.
33
Purchasing Power Parity and Exchange Rate Determination
Derivation of Relative PPP: Assume that price of the home country Ph and the foreign country Pf are equal. Home and foreign country experiences inflation rate of πh and πf respectively. Home and foreign country price indices become Ph (1+ πh) and Pf (1+ πf) respectively. If πh > πf or πf > πh, PPP does not hold. Exchange rate will change to maintain the parity in purchasing power
34
Purchasing Power Parity and Exchange Rate Determination
Pf(1+f)(1+ef)=Ph(1+h), where ef represents the change in the value of the foreign currency Solving for ef we have (1+ef) = Ph(1+h)/ Pf(1+f); or ef= [(1+h)/ (1+f)]-1 -since we assumed that Ph and Pf were initially equal in both countries. The formula reflects the relationship between relative inflation rate and the exchange rate. The formula can also be expressed as e=(h- f)/(1+f) which can be approximated by e= h- f
35
Purchasing Power Parity and Exchange Rate Determination
If h> f , ef should be positive foreign currency will appreciate when home country’s inflation exceeds the foreign country’s inflation. If f> h, ef should be negative foreign currency will depreciate when foreign country’s inflation exceeds the home country’s inflation. Relative PPP states that the rate of change in an exchange rate is equal to the differences in the rates of inflation. e = h - f If U.S. inflation is 5% and U.K. inflation is 8%, the pound should depreciate by 3%.
36
Purchasing Power Parity and Exchange Rate Determination
PPP and monetary approach, associated with Chicago School Based on two basic tenets: PPP and quantity theory of money From quantity theory of money the following identity must hold for each country Ph=MhVh/yh, and Pf=MfVf/yf where M denotes money supply, V the velocity of money, y the national aggregate output, P is the general price level Substituting the above two equations are substituted for the price levels in the PPP equation, we have: S = Ph / Pf = (Mh/Mf)(Vh/Vf)(yh/yf
37
Purchasing Power Parity and Exchange Rate Determination
According to the monetary approach, what matters in exchange rate determination are: The relative money supplies The relative velocity of money The relative national outputs All else equal an increase in home money supply will result in proportionate depreciation of the home currency so will an increase in velocity of home currency, which is the same as increase in supply of home currency; But increase in home output will cause appreciation of home currency The monetary approach can be viewed as a long-run theory It assumes prices adjusts fully and completely In the short run there are price rigidities such as wage rate set by labor contract
38
PPP Deviations and the Real Exchange Rate
If PPP holds and thus differential inflation rates between countries are exactly offset by exchange rate changes, countries’ competitive positions in world export market will not be systematically affected by exchange rate changes. If there are deviations, changes in the nominal exchange rate cause changes in the real exchange rates, affecting international competitiveness and thus trade balances.
39
PPP Deviations and the Real Exchange Rate
The real exchange rate is: q= (1 + h)/[(1 + e)(1 + f)] If PPP holds, (1 + e) = (1 + h)/(1 + f), then q = 1. If q < 1 competitiveness of domestic country improves with currency depreciations. If q = 1 competitiveness of domestic country unaltered with currency depreciations If q > 1 competitiveness of domestic country deteriorates with currency depreciations. Real exchange rate measures deviations from PPP. If PPP holds, the denominator becomes 1 + h Suppose annual inflation rate is 5 percent in the US and 3.5 percent in the UK and dollar depreciated against the pound by 4.5 percent the real exchange rate is q = (1.05)/[(1.045)x(1.035)= 0.97 In the example, the dollar depreciated by more than is warranted by PPP, strengthening competitiveness of US. If the dollar depreciates by less than the interest rate differential, the real exchange rate will be greater than unity, weakening the competitiveness of US
40
Evidence on PPP PPP probably doesn’t hold precisely in the real world for a variety of reasons. Substantial barriers to international commodity arbitrage exists Haircuts cost 10 times as much in the developed world as in the developing world: non-tradeables. Shipping costs, as well as tariffs and quotas can lead to deviations from PPP. PPP-determined exchange rates still provide a valuable benchmark In deciding if if a country’s currency is overvalued or undervalued. Can often be used to make more meaningful international comparisons of economic data using PPP-determined rather than market determined exchange rates. Size of the economy
41
Comparison of GNP Per Capita
Country GNP per Capita US$ PPP Remarks Bangladesh 350 1,407 Higher PPP GNP per Capita India 440 2,060 Nepal 210 1,181 Pakistan 470 1,652 Singapore 30,170 25,295 Lower PPP GNP per Capita Japan 32,350 23,592 Malaysia 3,670 7,699 Thailand 2,160 5,524 China 750 3051
42
The Fisher Effects An increase (decrease) in the expected rate of inflation will cause a proportionate increase (decrease) in the interest rate in the country. For the home country, the Fisher effect is written as: ih = h + E(h) Where h is the equilibrium expected “real” home country’s interest rate E(h) is the expected rate of home country’s inflation ih is the equilibrium expected nominal home interest rate ih = 2%(expected real interest rate) + 4%(expected inflation rate) =6%
43
International Fisher Effect
If the Fisher effect holds in the home country ih = h + E(h) and the Fisher effect holds in the foreign country if = f + E(f) and if the real rates are the same in each h = f then we get the International Fisher Effect E(e) = ih - if . Ih- if = h + E(h) - f - E(f) or E(h) - E(f)= Ih- if International Fisher Effect (IFE) suggests that the nominal interest rate differential reflects the expected change in exchange rate. For example, if in the US the interest rate is 5% and 7% in the UK, the dollar is expected to appreciate against the pound by about 2% per year.
44
International Fisher Effect
If the International Fisher Effect holds, E(e) = ih - if and if IRP also holds ih – if =(F-S)/S Forward Expectations Parity states that any forward premium or discount is equal to the expected change in the exchange rate. then forward expectation parity holds.
45
Equilibrium Exchange Rate Relationships
IFE FEP PPP IRP With the assumption of the same real interest rate, the Fisher Effect(FE) implies that the interest rate differential is equal to the expected interest rate differential If PPP and FEP hold, then then forward exchange premium or discount will be equal to the expected inflation rate differential. This relationship is known as the forward PPP, FPPP. IFE stands for International Fisher effect FE FPPP $ - £
46
Forecasting Exchange Rates
Efficient Markets Approach Fundamental Approach Technical Approach Performance of the Forecasters
47
Efficient Markets Approach
Financial Markets are efficient if prices reflect all available and relevant information. If this is so, exchange rates will only change when new information arrives, which is unpredictable. So, the exchange rate will change randomly over time. Thus, according to the random walk hypothesis, today’s exchange rate is the best predictor of tomorrow’s exchange rate: St = E[St+1] While researchers found it difficult to reject the random walk hypothesis on empirical grounds, there is no theoretical base of this either.
48
Efficient Markets Approach
The parity relationships indicate that the current forward exchange rate can be viewed as the market’s consensus forecast of the future exchange rate based on the available information (It) if the foreign exchange markets are efficient, that is, Ft = E[St+1| It] To the extent that interest rates are different between two countries, the forward exchange rates will be different from the current spot exchange rate.
49
Efficient Markets Approach
The efficient market hypothesis subscriber may predict the future exchange rate using either the current spot exchange rate or the current forward exchange rate. But which one is better? The empirical findings indicate that these two models registered comparable performances. Predicting exchange rates using the efficient markets approach is affordable and is hard to beat. Advantages of efficient market hypothesis: Since both the current spot and forward exchange rates are public information, generating forecasts using EMH is costless and freely accessible. It is difficult to outperform the market-based forecasts unless the forecaster has access to private information that is not yet reflected in the current exchange rate.
50
Fundamental Approach The fundamental approach to exchange rate forecasting uses various models that involve econometrics using a variety of explanatory variables. This involves three steps: step 1: Estimate the structural model . step 2: Estimate future parameter values. step 3: Use the model to develop forecasts. The downside is that fundamental models do not work any better than the forward rate model or the random walk model. For example, the monetary approach to exchange rate determination uses three independent (explanatory) variables: relative money supplies relative velocity of monies relative national outputs Thus, the monetary approach can be formulated in the following empirical form: s = α + β1 (m-m*)+ β2 (v-v*) + β3(y*-y) + u Where: s = natural logarithm of the spot exchange rate m-m* = natural logarithm of domestic/foreign money supply v-v* = natural logarithm of domestic/foreign velocity of money (y*-y) = natural logarithm of foreign/domestic output u = random error term, with mean zero. α, β’s = model parameters. Generating Forecasts using the fundamental approach would involve three steps: Step 1: Estimation of the structural model like the above to determine the numerical values for the parameters such as α and β’s. Step 2: Estimation of future values of the independent variables like (m-m*), (v-v*), and (y*-y). Step 3: Substituting the estimated values of the independent variables into the estimated structural model to generate the exchange rate forecasts.
51
Fundamental Approach Difficulties of fundamental approach:
Forecasting a set of independent variables to forecast the exchange rates Forecasting the former will certainly be subject to errors and may not be necessarily easier than forecasting the latter The parameter values (α,β’s) that are estimated using historical data may change over time because of changes in government policies and/or the underlying structure of the economy. Either difficulty can diminish the accuracy of forecasts even if the model is correct. The model itself and thus, the resulting forecasting can be wrong. Researchers found that the fundamental models failed to more accurately forecast exchange rates than either the forward rate model or the random walk model. Meese and Rogoff (1983) found that the fundamental models developed based on the monetary approach did worse than the random walk model even if realized (true) values were used for the independent variables. In the words of Meese and Rogoff: Ignoring for the present the fact that the spot rate does no worse than the forward rate, the striking feature,,,,is that none of the models achieves lower, much less significantly lower, RMSE than the random walk model at any horizon….The structural models in particular fail to improve on the random walk model in spite of the fact that their forecast are based on realized value of the explanatory variables.
52
Technical Approach Technical analysis looks for patterns in the past behavior of exchange rates and then projects them into the future to generate forecasts. Clearly it is based upon the premise that history repeats itself. Thus it is at odds with the EMH and differs from fundamental approach in that it does not use the key economic variables such as money supplies or trade balances for forecasting exchange rates. Example: Moving average crossover rule. Moving averages are computed as a way of separating short- and long-term trends from the vicissitudes of daily exchange rates and exchange rates may be forecasted based on the movements of short term moving average(SMA) and long-term moving average(LMA).
53
Moving Average Crossover Rule: A Technical Analysis
$/£ D LMA A Since SMA weighs recent exchange rates more heavily than the LMA, the SMA will lie below (above) the LMA when the British pound is falling (rising) against the dollar. This implies that exchange rate movements can be forecasted based on the crossover of the moving averages. According to the moving average rule, a crossover of the SMA above the LMA at point A signals that the British pound is appreciating. On the other hand, a crossover of the SMA below the LMA at point D signals that the British pound is depreciating. SMA tA tD Time
54
Technical Analysis While academic studies tend to discredit the validity of technical analysis, many traders depend on technical analysis for their trading strategies. If enough traders use this, the predictions based on it can become self-fulfilling to some extent, at least in the short run.
55
Performance of the Forecasters
Instead of using market-determined price such as the forward exchange rate, some firms and investors subscribe to professional forecasting services for a fee. But can professional forecasters outperform the market? Professor Richard Levich of New York University evaluated the performance of 13 forecasting services that uses different methods of forecasting (econometrics, technical and judgmental) using the forward exchange rate as a benchmark–the market’s consensus forecast of future exchange rate under certain conditions. In evaluating the performance of forecasters, Levich computed the following ratio: R = MAE (S)/ MAE (F) where: MAE (S) = mean absolute forecast error of a forecasting service MAE (F) = mean absolute forecast error of the forward exchange rate as a predictor If MAE (S) < MAE (F), the ratio R will be less than unity for the service =Professional forecasting provides more accurate forecasts than the forward exchange rate.
56
Performance of the Forecasters
Findings: 24% (25 out of 104) are less than unity, that is, professional services clearly failed to outperform the forward exchange rate. There are substantial variations in the performance records across individual services and also across currencies, which suggests that consumers need to discriminate among forecasting services depending on what currencies they are interested in. Eun and Sabherwal (2002) evaluated the forecasting performance of 10 major commercial banks around the world using the spot exchange rate as the benchmark. As a whole, they could not outperform the random walk model. As a whole, forecasters cannot do a better job of forecasting future exchange rates than the forward rate. The founder of Forbes Magazine once said: “You can make more money selling advice than following it.”
57
IRP and Covered Interest Arbitrage
If IRP failed to hold, an arbitrage would exist. It’s easiest to see this in the form of an example. Consider the following set of foreign and domestic interest rates and spot and forward exchange rates. Spot exchange rate S($/£) = $1.25/£ 360-day forward rate F360($/£) $1.20/£ U.S. discount rate i$ 7.10% British discount rate i£ 11.56%
58
IRP and Covered Interest Arbitrage
A trader with $1,000 to invest could invest in the U.S., in one year his investment will be worth $1,071 = $1,000(1+ i$) = $1,000(1.071) Alternatively, this trader could exchange $1,000 for £800 at the prevailing spot rate, (note that £800 = $1,000÷$1.25/£) invest £800 at i£ = 11.56% for one year to achieve £ Translate £ back into dollars at F360($/£) = $1.20/£, the £ will be exactly $1,071.
59
Interest Rate Parity & Exchange Rate Determination
According to IRP only one 360-day forward rate, F360($/£), can exist. It must be the case that F360($/£) = $1.20/£ Why? If F360($/£) $1.20/£, an astute trader could make money with one of the following strategies:
60
Arbitrage Strategy I If F360($/£) > $1.20/£
i. Borrow $1,000 at t = 0 at i$ = 7.1%. ii. Exchange $1,000 for £800 at the prevailing spot rate, (note that £800 = $1,000÷$1.25/£) invest £800 at 11.56% (i£) for one year to achieve £892.48 iii. Translate £ back into dollars, if F360($/£) > $1.20/£ , £ will be more than enough to repay your dollar obligation of $1,071.
61
Arbitrage Strategy II If F360($/£) < $1.20/£
i. Borrow £800 at t = 0 at i£= 11.56% . ii. Exchange £800 for $1,000 at the prevailing spot rate, invest $1,000 at 7.1% for one year to achieve $1,071. iii. Translate $1,071 back into pounds, if F360($/£) < $1.20/£ , $1,071 will be more than enough to repay your £ obligation of £
62
IRP and Hedging Currency Risk
You are a U.S. importer of British woolens and have just ordered next year’s inventory. Payment of £100M is due in one year. Spot exchange rate S($/£) = $1.25/£ 360-day forward rate F360($/£) $1.20/£ U.S. discount rate i$ 7.10% British discount rate i£ 11.56% IRP implies that there are two ways that you fix the cash outflow a) Put yourself in a position that delivers £100M in one year—a long forward contract on the pound. You will pay (£100M)(1.2/£) = $120M b) Form a forward market hedge as shown below. 4
63
IRP and a Forward Market Hedge
To form a forward market hedge: Borrow $ million in the U.S. (in one year you will owe $120 million). Translate $ million into pounds at the spot rate S($/£) = $1.25/£ to receive £89.64 million. Invest £89.64 million in the UK at i£ = 11.56% for one year. In one year your investment will have grown to £100 million—exactly enough to pay your supplier. 4
64
Forward Market Hedge Where do the numbers come from? We owe our supplier £100 million in one year—so we know that we need to have an investment with a future value of £100 million. Since i£ = 11.56% we need to invest £89.64 million at the start of the year. How many dollars will it take to acquire £89.64 million at the start of the year if S($/£) = $1.25/£? 4
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.