Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
1
8 Possibilities, Preferences, and Choices
CHAPTER Possibilities, Preferences, and Choices Notes and teaching tips: 4, 15, 30, 35, and 39. To view a full-screen figure during a class, click the red “expand” button. To return to the previous slide, click the red “shrink” button. To advance to the next slide, click anywhere on the full screen figure.
2
After studying this chapter you will be able to
Describe a household’s budget line and show how it changes when prices or income change Make a map of preferences by using indifference curves and explain the principle of diminishing marginal rate of substitution Predict the effects of changes in prices and income on consumption choices Predict the effects of changes in wage rates on work-leisure choices
3
Subterranean Movements
Like the continents floating on the earth’s mantle, spending patterns change slowly over time, but as they change, business empires rise and fall. The model of consumer choice that we study in this chapter explains such things as: Why as the prices of a music download, iPod, and CD burner have fallen, people are buying more downloads and fewer CDs. Why we don’t (much) buy too many electronic textbooks, even though they are cheaper than printed textbooks.
4
Consumption Possibilities
Household consumption choices are constrained by its income and the prices of the goods and services available. The budget line describes the limits to the household’s consumption choices. The budget line is like a restaurant menu. This example has been well received: Emphasize that the consumer’s budget line is like a menu showing what affordable combinations of food and drink are available to the consumer. Ask them to compare the relative prices between two goods: food and drink and depict the affordable combinations a diner can purchase with a set income.
5
Consumption Possibilities
Figure 8.1 shows Lisa’s budget line. Divisible goods can be bought in any quantity along the budget line (gasoline, for example). Indivisible goods must be bought in whole units at the points marked (movies, for example). Lisa can afford any point on the budget line or inside it.
7
Consumption Possibilities
The budget line is a constraint on Lisa’s choices. Lisa can afford any point on her budget line or inside it. Lisa cannot afford any point outside her budget line.
8
Consumption Possibilities
The Budget Equation We can describe the budget line by using a budget equation. The budget equation states that Expenditure = Income Call the price of soda PS, the quantity of soda QS, the price of a movie PM, the quantity of movies QM, and income Y. Lisa’s budget equation is: PSQS + PMQM = Y.
9
Consumption Possibilities
PSQS + PMQM = Y Divide both sides of this equation by PS, to give: QS + (PM/PS)QM = Y/PS Then subtract (PM/PS)QM from both sides of the equation to give: QS = Y/PS – (PM/PS)QM The term Y/PS is Lisa’s real income in terms of soda. The term PM/PS is the relative price of a movie in terms of soda.
10
Consumption Possibilities
A household’s real income is the income expressed as a quantity of goods the household can afford to buy. Lisa’s real income in terms of soda is the point on her budget line where it meets the y-axis. A relative price is the price of one good divided by the price of another good. Relative price is the magnitude of the slope of the budget line. The relative price shows how many sodas must be forgone to see an additional movie.
11
Consumption Possibilities
A Change in Prices A rise in the price of the good on the x-axis decreases the affordable quantity of that good and increases the slope of the budget line. Figure 8.2(a) shows the rotation of a budget line after a change in the relative price of movies.
13
Consumption Possibilities
A Change in Income An change in money income brings a parallel shift of the budget line. The slope of the budget line doesn’t change because the relative price doesn’t change. Figure 8.2(b) shows the effect of a fall in income.
15
Preferences and Indifference Curves
An indifference curve is a line that shows combinations of goods among which a consumer is indifferent. Figure 8.3(a) illustrates a consumer’s indifference curve. At point C, Lisa consumes 2 movies and 6 six-packs a month. Decisions, decisions: Chardonnay or cheesecake? What combination of food and drink will the diner select? It depends upon the willingness to give up some food for additional drink. Is the diner willing to forgo the appetizer in order to enjoy a second glass of wine with dinner? Or will the diner have only ice water in order to afford a dessert after the main course? Have them construct a preference map reflecting the diner’s indifference between exchanging a quantity of drink for a quantity of food. (Be sure that the indifference curves for both scenarios reflect diminishing marginal rate of substitution.)
17
Preferences and Indifference Curves
Lisa can sort all possible combinations of goods into three groups: preferred, not preferred, and indifferent. An indifference curve joins all those points that Lisa says are just as good as C. G is such a point. Lisa is indifferent between C and G.
18
Preferences and Indifference Curves
All the points above the indifference curve are preferred to the points on the curve. And all the points on the indifference curve are preferred to the points below the curve.
19
Preferences and Indifference Curves
A preference map is series of indifference curves. Call the indifference curve that we’ve just seen I1. I0 is an indifference curve below I1. Lisa prefers any point on I1 to any point on I0 .
21
Preferences and Indifference Curves
I2 is an indifference curve above I1. Lisa prefers any point on I2 to any point on I1 . For example, Lisa prefers point J to either point C or point G.
22
Preferences and Indifference Curves
Marginal Rate of Substitution The marginal rate of substitution, (MRS) measures the rate at which a person is willing to give up good y, (the good measured on the y-axis) to get an additional unit of good x (the good measured on the x-axis) and at the same time remain indifferent (remain on the same indifference curve). The magnitude of the slope of the indifference curve measures the marginal rate of substitution.
23
Preferences and Indifference Curves
If the indifference curve is relatively steep, the MRS is high. In this case, the person is willing to give up a large quantity of y to get a bit more x. If the indifference curve is relatively flat, the MRS is low. In this case, the person is willing to give up a small quantity of y to get more x.
24
Preferences and Indifference Curves
A diminishing marginal rate of substitution is the key assumption of consumer theory. A diminishing marginal rate of substitution is a general tendency for a person to be willing to give up less of good y to get one more unit of good x, and at the same time remain indifferent, as the quantity of good x increases.
25
Preferences and Indifference Curves
Figure 8.4 shows the diminishing MRS of movies for soda. At point C, Lisa is willing to give up 2 six-packs to see one more movie—her MRS is 2. At point G, Lisa is willing to give up 1/2 a six-pack to see one more movie—her MRS is 1/2.
27
Preferences and Indifference Curves
Degree of Substitutability The shape of the indifference curves reveals the degree of substitutability between two goods. Figure 8.5 shows the indifference curves for ordinary goods, perfects substitutes, and perfect complements.
29
Predicting Consumer Behavior
The consumer’s best affordable point is: On the budget line On the highest attainable indifference curve Has a marginal rate of substitution between the two goods equal to the relative price of the two goods
30
Predicting Consumer Behavior
Here, the best affordable point is C. Lisa can afford to consume more soda and see fewer movies at point F. And she can afford to see more movies and consume less soda at point H. But she is indifferent between F, I, and H and she clearly prefers C to I. Waiter? We’re ready to order now. Have the students identify which combination of food and drink would equate the MRS to the relative price ratio for a given budget. Have the students show how a rise in the price of drinks would rotate the budget line and push the diner away from drink and toward food. Show how an increase in income shifts the budget line, allowing both dessert and the second glass of wine. The meaning of tangency. Emphasize to the student the meaning behind the tangency point between the indifference curve and the budget line. The marginal rate of substitution (MRS) shows the consumer’s willingness to give up one good to get more of the other good. The relative price of the two goods shows what the consumer must give up one good to get more of the other good. When a consumer equates the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) with the relative price ratio, he or she leaves no unrealized gains from substituting one good for another. The consumer is just willing to give up what he or she must give up, and there are no unrealized gains from substituting one good for another.
32
Predicting Consumer Behavior
At point F, Lisa’s MRS is greater than the relative price. At point H, Lisa’s MRS is less than the relative price. At point C, Lisa’s MRS is equal to the relative price.
33
Predicting … A Change in Price
The effect of a change in the price of a good on the quantity of the good consumed is called the price effect. Figure 8.7 illustrates the price effect and shows how the consumer’s demand curve is generated. Initially, the price of a movie is $6 and Lisa consumes at point C in part (a) and at point A in part (b).
35
Predicting … The price of a movie then falls to $3.
The budget line rotates outward. Lisa’s best affordable point is now J in part (a). Explain that the fall in the price of a movie leads Lisa to substitute away from sodas and into movies. The change in the relative price changes the best affordable point. She can reach a higher indifference curve by substituting away from the relatively more expensive good and toward the relatively inexpensive good. The new consumption bundle satisfies the three properties: it is on the new budget line, it is on the highest attainable indifference curve, and the MRS has changed, matching the slope of new budget line. Also emphasize that tracking the change in the quantity of the good for which the price falls reveals the demand curve for that good. In part (b), Lisa moves to point B, which is a movement along her demand curve for movies.
36
Predicting … A Change in Income
The effect of a change in income on the quantity of a good consumed is called the income effect. Figure 8.8 illustrates the effect of a decrease in Lisa’s income. Initially, Lisa consumes at point J in part (a) and at point B on demand curve D0 in part (b).
38
Predicting … Lisa’s income decreases and her budget line shifts leftward in part (a). Her new best affordable point is K in part (a). Her demand for movies decreases, shown by a leftward shift of her demand curve for movies in part (b).
39
Predicting Consumer Behavior
Substitution Effect and Income Effect For a normal good, a fall in price always increases the quantity consumed. We can prove this assertion by dividing the price effect in two parts: Substitution effect Income effect Students find this topic hard. Take it slowly. Get the students to tell you how it goes. That’s the best way of judging the pace that will work for them.
40
Predicting Consumer Behavior
Initially, Lisa has an income of $30, the price of a movie is $6, and she consumes at point C. The price of a movie falls from $6 to $3 and her budget line rotates outward. Lisa’s best affordable point is then J. The move from point C to point J is the price effect.
42
Predicting Consumer Behavior
We’re going to break the move from point C to point J into two parts. The first part is the substitution effect and the second is the income effect.
43
Predicting Consumer Behavior
Substitution Effect The substitution effect is the effect of a change in price on the quantity bought when the consumer remains indifferent between the original situation and the new situation.
45
Predicting Consumer Behavior
To isolate the substitution effect, we give Lisa a hypothetical pay cut. Lisa is now back on her original indifference curve but with a lower price of movies and her best affordable point is K. The move from C to K is the substitution effect.
47
Predicting Consumer Behavior
The direction of the substitution effect never varies: When the relative price falls, the consumer always substitutes more of that good for other goods. The substitution effect is the first reason why the demand curve slopes downward.
48
Predicting Consumer Behavior
Income Effect To isolate the income effect, we reverse the hypothetical pay cut and restore Lisa’s income to its original level (its actual level). Lisa is now back on indifference curve I2 and her best affordable point is J. The move from K to J is the income effect.
50
Predicting Consumer Behavior
For Lisa, movies are a normal good. When her income increases, she sees more movies—the income effect is positive. For a normal good, the income effect reinforces the substitution effect and is the second reason why the demand curve slopes downward.
51
Predicting Consumer Behavior
Inferior Good For an inferior good, when income increases, the quantity bought decreases. For an inferior good, the income effect works against the substitution effect. So long as the substitution effect dominates, the demand curve still slopes downward.
52
Predicting Consumer Behavior
If the negative income effect is stronger than the substitution effect, a lower price for inferior goods brings a decrease in the quantity demanded—the demand curve slopes upward! This case does not appear to occur in the real world.
53
Work-Leisure Choices The model of consumer choice can be used to study the allocation of time between work and leisure. The two “goods” are leisure and income—where income represents all other goods. Lisa buys leisure by not supplying labor and by forgoing income. So the “price” of leisure is the wage rate forgone.
54
Work-Leisure Choices The Labor Supply Curve
By changing the wage rate, we can find a person’s labor supply curve. An increase in the wage rate makes leisure relatively more expensive (higher opportunity cost to not working) and has a substitution effect toward less leisure (toward more work).
56
Work-Leisure Choices A higher wage also has a positive income effect on leisure. If the income effect is weaker than the substitution effect, the quantity of work hours increases as the wage rate rises. When the wage rate rises from $5 to $10 an hour, work increases from 20 to 35 hours a week—the move from A to B.
57
Work-Leisure Choices But if the income effect is stronger than the substitution effect, the quantity of work hours decreases as the wage rate rises. When the wage rate rises from $10 to $15 an hour, work decreases from 35 to 30 hours a week —the move from B to C.
58
Work-Leisure Choices The move from A to B when the wage rate increases from $5 to $10 an hour means that the labor supply curve slopes upward over this range. The move from B to C when the wage rate increases from $10 to $15 an hour means that the labor supply curve bends backward above a certain wage rate.
60
Work-Leisure Choices Historical evidence shows that the average workweek has declined over the centuries, implying that people have preferred to seek greater leisure despite its higher opportunity cost.
61
THE END
Similar presentations
© 2024 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.