Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
1
Fisheries Science and Political Expediency: Can the Two be Reconciled? An address at the FAME workshop Social and natural science in marine renewable resources University of Southern Denmark June 6-8 2007 Ragnar Arnason
2
Organization of Talk I.The fisheries management problem II.Who is responsible? III.Why fisheries mismanagement? IV.A possible solution V.Main conclusions: Summary
3
Section I. The fisheries management problem
4
The global (marine) fishery (FAO data) Substantial stock overexploitation (Stocks: 2/3 of stocks≤MSY, 1/3 severely depleted) Excessive fishing capital (Global fleet 20-25 m. GRT; 2-3 times needed) Excessive fishing effort (Approximately 2 times what is optimal) Little net economic benefits (Losses 5-10 billion USD; most fishermen are poor)
5
Global Fisheries Rents Loss
6
Current Optimal Global fishery: Illustration
7
Global fishery: Another view Biomass Growth, yield Current Optimal
8
Individual fisheries Pretty much the same applies to individual fisheries –Few exceptions (less than 1/5 of global fisheries) Global fisheries mismanagement of great proportions!
9
Section II Who is responsible?
10
Governments are responsible !! Have (formal) fisheries management powers –Over time have usurped rights to (ocean) fisheries –This is demonstrated by historical research (A. Scott, England, the colonies, Denmark, Iceland, USA etc.) Have taken (at least ”de facto”) ownership of many/most natural resources –Sovereignty powers –Environment, many commercial resources (e.g. land), wild animals etc. No-one else has management powers
11
Why have governments mismanaged?- - Four hypotheses - 1.Lack of fisheries science understanding No – Well known for over 50 years (Warming 1911, Gordon 1954, Scott 1955 etc.) Plenty of material, arguments and pleadings Much better understood that many other fields of science into which money is poured 2.Lack of fisheries management understanding No – Well known for over 25 years (Scott 1955, Christy 1973, Arnason 1977, Mploney and Pearse 1979) (Evidence: Holland, Iceland 1976, New Zealand 1982 ….etc.)
12
Four hypotheses (cont) 3.Lack of data No - Do not really need much data for reasonable management (basically MSY and MSY x will do fine ) - For most fisheries, ample data available 4.Lack of will (political will) ! This hypthesis I cannot reject!
13
Example: The Icelandic cod fishery Economically very important Very well researched and understood Nevertheless, poorly managed Management history –Pre 1976: Almost no management (inadequate national control) –1976-78: TAC regime –1978-84: Effort/capital restrictions –1984-90: ITQ/effort limitations mix –1991-04: ITQs with exceptions (small vessels) –2004-?: ITQs
14
Problems with governments as fisheries managers Information problems –Must collect a great deal of data from the fishery (i)Fishers’ profit functions (ii) Fish stocks –Much of these data exist within the fishing industry Incentive problems (i)Perverse incentives (ii)Misalignment of benefits and costs (iii)Rent-seeking
15
Icelandic cod: Actual vs. optimal harvest
16
Icelandic cod: Catch rule (set 1995) 25% catch rule Optimal rule
17
Icelandic cod: Actual vs. optimal harvesting
18
Conclusions At least for Icelandic cod, governments are unwilling to do good fisheries management It had (i) strong theory (ii) lot of good research and (iii) lot of empirical evidence Nevertheless chose to do bad management Icelandic case probably exemplifies other fisheries around the world
19
Section III Why?
20
Why choose to mismanage? Focus on two reasons: 1.Perverse (inappropriate) incentives 2.Misalignment of benefits and costs
21
Basic premises i.Government ={Politicians, civil servants} ii.Both seek to maximize their own benefits iii.Their benefits include power as well as income (usually go hand in hand) iv.Politicians need to –be able to allocate benefits (patronage, public funds in various forms) –Satisfy their special constituencies Otherwise they are not re-elected
22
Perverse incentives The holders of government power –Are interested in their own welfare –Are supposed to manage fisheries –They bear few consequences of their management –They do not benefit (at least not directly) from good fisheries management –They are normally not punished for poor fisheries management So perverse incentives!
23
Political cost-benefit calculation of improved fisheries management Benefits: –Voters grateful? –A thorny problem gone? Costs: –Some losers (workers, suppliers, regions. …Losers are hateful; seek to punish. The press invariably supports them) –No more patronage to allocate (supports, funds => weaker political power) –Reduced size of bureaucracies –Uncertainty (of the outcome of a new controversial action) An unattractive proposal – bad project
24
Democratic decision making: A simple example Exogenous flow of benefits: y(t) Share of population: z(t) Share of government: y(t)-z(t) Utility functions: V(z(t)), U(y(t) - z(t)) Social welfare W(v,u) Elections at time T Terminal value to government S(T), s´(t)= z(t) Holders of government maximize their present value of benefits
25
Assuming simple functional forms (logrithmic utility functions) the following can be derived: Time z T Socially optimal Political allocation
26
Misalignment of benefits and costs Fisheries management belongs to box I ! Virtually every policy has winners and losers Losers of improved fisheries management (suppliers, workers, certain regions, certain distributers, some government groups) Gainers (fishery capital owners, crews, some government groups)
27
Section IV A solution
28
Give fisheries management rights to fishers No (few) perverse incentives Benefits and costs better aligned Coase type of an efficient solution possible !! (Really a Nash co-operative solution to the bargaining game)
29
What form should the rights take Many possibilities –Group rights (community of fishers) –Sole owner rights –Individual rights (e.g. ITQs, TURFS, shares) Must be high quality (Coase) –Exclusivity –Security –Durability –Tradability
30
Specific examples Shares in total benefits (like shares in a company) Individual transferable quotas (ITQs) Both can be pretty strong property rights
31
Shares in total benefits Total benefits: V(a), a=vector of management actions Individual benefits: (i)=s(i) V(a) Max (i)=Max s(i) V(a)=s(i) Max V(a) Max V(a) So, each share-holder will want to maximize the total value of the fishery!
32
ITQs (A bit more complicated) Total benefits: V(Q), Q=time path of total quota Individual benefits: (i)=b(i) V(Q), all i (identical apart from scale) So, each ITQ-holder will want to maximize the total value of the fishery! Max (i)=Max b(i) V(Q)=b(i) Max V(Q) Max V(a) Can generalize this result!
33
What has been demonstrated Fishers’ rights to manage themselves may result in efficiency –That will almost always lead to large stocks –That will generallyfacilitate accommodation of other interests –It will usually not be regarded as fair Under certain arrangements (shares, ITQs) it probably will Clearly, a favourable outcome can be helped by the proper arrangement of rights and negotiation
34
Section V Conclusions
35
Huge global fisheries mismanagement Governments are responsible Objective reasons for that outcome –Perverse incentives and misaligned costs/benefits –Fundamental and lasting problem with government Not a question of bridging a gap between science and politicians By-pass the government problem by giving fisheries management rights back to fishers Need to research the best arrangment for that –Closed shop –Coercive powers –Cost recovery (tax) powers
36
END
Similar presentations
© 2024 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.