Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
1
Multi-unit auctions & exchanges (multiple indistinguishable units of one item for sale) Tuomas Sandholm Computer Science Department Carnegie Mellon University
2
Auctions with multiple indistinguishable units for sale Examples –IBM stocks –Barrels of oil –Pork bellies –Trans-Atlantic backbone bandwidth from NYC to Paris –…
3
Multi-unit auctions: pricing rules Auctioning multiple indistinguishable units of an item Naive generalization of the Vickrey auction: uniform price auction –If there are k units for sale, the highest k bids win, and each bid pays the k+1st highest price –Demand reduction lie [Crampton&Ausubel 96]: k=5 Agent 1 values getting her first unit at $9, and getting a second unit is worth $7 to her Others have placed bids $2, $6, $8, $10, and $14 If agent 1 submits one bid at $9 and one at $7, she gets both items, and pays 2 x $6 = $12. Her utility is $9 + $7 - $12 = $4 If agent 1 only submits one bid for $9, she will get one item, and pay $2. Her utility is $9-$2=$7 Incentive compatible mechanism that is Pareto efficient and ex post individually rational –Clarke tax. Agent i pays a-b b is the others’ sum of winning bids a is the others’ sum of winning bids had i not participated –What about revenue (if market is competitive)?
4
Multi-unit auctions: Clearing complexity [Sandholm & Suri IJCAI-01]
13
In all of the curves together
24
Multi-unit reverse auctions with supply curves Same complexity results apply as in auctions –O(#pieces log #pieces) in nondiscriminatory case with piecewise linear supply curves –NP-complete in discriminatory case with piecewise linear supply curves –O(#agents log #agents) in discriminatory case with linear supply curves
25
Multi-unit exchanges Multiple buyers, multiple sellers, multiple units for sale By Myerson-Satterthwaite thrm, even in 1- unit case cannot obtain all of Pareto efficiency Budget balance Individual rationality (participation)
26
Screenshot from eMediator [Sandholm AGENTS-00]
27
Supply/demand curve bids profit = amounts paid by bidders – amounts paid to sellers Can be divided between buyers, sellers & market maker Unit price Quantity Aggregate supply Aggregate demand One price for everyone (“classic partial equilibrium”): profit = 0 One price for sellers, one for buyers ( nondiscriminatory pricing ): profit > 0 profit p sell p buy
28
Nondiscriminatory vs. discriminatory pricing Unit price Quantity Supply of agent 1 Aggregate demand Supply of agent 2 One price for sellers, one for buyers ( nondiscriminatory pricing ): profit > 0 p sell p buy One price for each agent ( discriminatory pricing ): greater profit p1 sell p buy p2 sell
29
Shape of supply/demand curves Piecewise linear curve can approximate any curve Assume –Each buyer’s demand curve is downward sloping –Each seller’s supply curve is upward sloping –Otherwise absurd result can occur Aggregate curves might not be monotonic Even individuals’ curves might not be continuous
30
Pricing scheme has implications on time complexity of clearing Piecewise linear curves (not necessarily continuous) can approximate any curve Clearing objective: maximize profit Thrm. Nondiscriminatory clearing with piecewise linear supply/demand: O(p log p) –p = total number of pieces in the curves Thrm. Discriminatory clearing with piecewise linear supply/demand: NP-complete Thrm. Discriminatory clearing with linear supply/demand: O(a log a) –a = number of agents These results apply to auctions, reverse auctions, and exchanges So, there is an inherent tradeoff between profit and computational complexity
31
Multi-unit reverse auctions with supply curves Same complexity results apply as in auctions –O(#pieces log #pieces) in nondiscriminatory case with piecewise linear supply curves –NP-complete in discriminatory case with piecewise linear supply curves –O(#agents log #agents) in discriminatory case with linear supply curves
Similar presentations
© 2024 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.