Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
1
The Consumer Theory How Consumers Make Choices under Income Constraints
2
Some Questions What is behind a consumer’s demand curve? What is behind a consumer’s demand curve? How do consumers choose from among various consumer “goods”? How do consumers choose from among various consumer “goods”? What determines the value of a consumer good? What determines the value of a consumer good?
3
Preferences Behavioral Assumption: Each person has his/her own preferences over bundles. Behavioral Assumption: Each person has his/her own preferences over bundles. A person can rank two bundles A and B. Either A person can rank two bundles A and B. Either A is preferred to B A is preferred to B B is preferred to A B is preferred to A A is indifferent to B A is indifferent to B One person may prefer A to B whilst another prefers B to A. One person may prefer A to B whilst another prefers B to A.
4
Properties The preferences are assumed to have the following reasonable properties: The preferences are assumed to have the following reasonable properties: I. More is better. If bundle A has strictly more of one good and does not have less of any good than bundle B, then all consumers prefer A to B. I. More is better. If bundle A has strictly more of one good and does not have less of any good than bundle B, then all consumers prefer A to B. II. Transitivity. A better than B better than C means A better than C. II. Transitivity. A better than B better than C means A better than C. III. A preferred to B means B is not preferred to A. III. A preferred to B means B is not preferred to A.
5
More is Better Bread Wine Point, A, in Bread-Wine space is a bundle A These points have more bread or wine or both. Every consumer prefers them to A Worse than A for all. ? ?
6
Indifference curves. Two bundles are indifferent (for a particular consumer) if the consumer is equally happy with either bundle. Two bundles are indifferent (for a particular consumer) if the consumer is equally happy with either bundle. (If one added the teeniest bit of any good to one of the bundles, then the consumer would prefer it.) (If one added the teeniest bit of any good to one of the bundles, then the consumer would prefer it.) Let A be a bundle. There is an indifference curve through A. Let A be a bundle. There is an indifference curve through A. The indifference curve through A is the set of all bundles that makes the consumer just as happy as bundle A. The indifference curve through A is the set of all bundles that makes the consumer just as happy as bundle A.
7
Properties. Indifference curves slope down. Indifference curves slope down. They do not cross. They do not cross. Higher indifference curves are better. Higher indifference curves are better. For reasons that I don't care to discuss, I always draw them so that they look like a crescent moon. For reasons that I don't care to discuss, I always draw them so that they look like a crescent moon.
8
A Demonstration B W a b c Every point on the higher indifference curve is better because b is preferred to a by more is better, c is indifferent to b because they are on the same indifference curve and therefore c is preferred to a.
9
Indiff. Curves Don’t Cross B W a b c Use more is better and transitivity to construct the proof
10
Which Bundle? B W c d e f Of the bundles a consumer can afford, the consumer chooses the one the consumer likes most. Remember: Higher indifference curve, like more.
11
Inferior and Normal When income increases the quantity purchased of a normal good also increases. When income increases the quantity purchased of a normal good also increases. When income increases, the quantity purchased of an inferior good decreases When income increases, the quantity purchased of an inferior good decreases B W
12
Utility The value a consumer places on a unit of a good or service depends on the pleasure or satisfaction he or she expects to derive form having or consuming it at the point of making a consumption (consumer) choice. The value a consumer places on a unit of a good or service depends on the pleasure or satisfaction he or she expects to derive form having or consuming it at the point of making a consumption (consumer) choice. In economics the satisfaction or pleasure consumers derive from the consumption of consumer goods is called “utility”. In economics the satisfaction or pleasure consumers derive from the consumption of consumer goods is called “utility”. Consumers, however, cannot have every thing they wish to have. Consumers’ choices are constrained by their incomes. Consumers, however, cannot have every thing they wish to have. Consumers’ choices are constrained by their incomes. Within the limits of their incomes, consumers make their consumption choices by evaluating and comparing consumer goods with regard to their “utilities.” Within the limits of their incomes, consumers make their consumption choices by evaluating and comparing consumer goods with regard to their “utilities.”
13
Our basic assumptions about a “rational” consumer: Consumers are utility maximizers Consumers are utility maximizers Consumers prefer more of a good (thing) to less of it. Consumers prefer more of a good (thing) to less of it. Facing choices X and Y, a consumer would either prefer X to Y or Y to X, or would be indifferent between them. Facing choices X and Y, a consumer would either prefer X to Y or Y to X, or would be indifferent between them. Transitivity: If a consumer prefers X to Y and Y to Z, we conclude he/she prefers X to Z Transitivity: If a consumer prefers X to Y and Y to Z, we conclude he/she prefers X to Z Diminishing marginal utility: As more and more of good is consumed by a consumer, ceteris paribus, beyond a certain point the utility of each additional unit starts to fall. Diminishing marginal utility: As more and more of good is consumed by a consumer, ceteris paribus, beyond a certain point the utility of each additional unit starts to fall.
14
How to Measure Utility Measuring utility in “utils” (Cardinal): Jack derives 10 utils from having one slice of pizza but only 5 utils from having a burger. Jack derives 10 utils from having one slice of pizza but only 5 utils from having a burger. In many introductory microeconomics textbooks this approach to measuring utility is still considered effective for teaching purposes. In many introductory microeconomics textbooks this approach to measuring utility is still considered effective for teaching purposes. Measuring utility by comparison (Ordinal): Jill prefers a burger to a slice of pizza and a slice of pizza to a hotdog. Jill prefers a burger to a slice of pizza and a slice of pizza to a hotdog. Often consumers are able to be more precise in expressing their preferences. For example, we could say: Jill is willing to trade a burger for four hotdogs but she will give up only two hotdogs for a slice of pizza. Jill is willing to trade a burger for four hotdogs but she will give up only two hotdogs for a slice of pizza. We can infer that to Jill, a burger has twice as much utility as a slice of pizza, and a slice of pizza has twice as much utility as a hotdog. We can infer that to Jill, a burger has twice as much utility as a slice of pizza, and a slice of pizza has twice as much utility as a hotdog.
15
Utility and Money Because we use money (rather than hotdogs!) in just about all of our trade transactions, we might as well use it as our comparative measure of utility. Because we use money (rather than hotdogs!) in just about all of our trade transactions, we might as well use it as our comparative measure of utility. (Note: This way of measuring utility is not much different (Note: This way of measuring utility is not much different from measuring utility in utils) from measuring utility in utils) Jill could say: I am willing to pay $4 for a burger, $2 for a slice of pizza and $1 for a hotdog. Jill could say: I am willing to pay $4 for a burger, $2 for a slice of pizza and $1 for a hotdog. Note: Even though Jill obviously values a burger more (four Note: Even though Jill obviously values a burger more (four times as much) than a hot dog, she may still choose to buy a times as much) than a hot dog, she may still choose to buy a hotdog, even if she has enough money to buy a burger, or a hotdog, even if she has enough money to buy a burger, or a slice of pizza, for that matter. (We will see why and how shortly.) slice of pizza, for that matter. (We will see why and how shortly.)
16
Total Utility versus Marginal Utility Marginal utility is the utility a consumer derives from the last unit of a consumer good she or he consumes (during a given consumption period), ceteris paribus. Marginal utility is the utility a consumer derives from the last unit of a consumer good she or he consumes (during a given consumption period), ceteris paribus. Total utility is the total utility a consumer derives from the consumption of all of the units of a good or a combination of goods over a given consumption period, ceteris paribus. Total utility is the total utility a consumer derives from the consumption of all of the units of a good or a combination of goods over a given consumption period, ceteris paribus. Total utility = Sum of marginal utilities Total utility = Sum of marginal utilities
17
The Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility Over a given consumption period, the more of a good a consumer has, or has consumed, the less marginal utility an additional unit contributes to his or her overall satisfaction (total utility). Over a given consumption period, the more of a good a consumer has, or has consumed, the less marginal utility an additional unit contributes to his or her overall satisfaction (total utility). Alternatively, we could say: over a given consumption period, as more and more of a good is consumed by a consumer, beyond a certain point, the marginal utility of additional units begins to fall. Alternatively, we could say: over a given consumption period, as more and more of a good is consumed by a consumer, beyond a certain point, the marginal utility of additional units begins to fall.
18
Total and Marginal Utility for Ice Cream
20
How much ice cream does Jill buy in a month? Some facts of life: Limited income Limited income Opportunity cost of making a choice: Opportunity cost of making a choice: Buying ice cream leaves Jill less money to buy other things: each dollar spent on ice cream could be spent on hamburger. buy other things: each dollar spent on ice cream could be spent on hamburger. In fact, consumers compare the (expected) utility derived from one additional dollar spent on one good to the utility derived from one additional dollar spent on another good. In fact, consumers compare the (expected) utility derived from one additional dollar spent on one good to the utility derived from one additional dollar spent on another good.
21
More facts The prices of hamburger and ice cream are market-given; the consumer cannot change the price of a good. The prices of hamburger and ice cream are market-given; the consumer cannot change the price of a good. Jill, like any other rational consumer, wishes to maximize her utility. Jill, like any other rational consumer, wishes to maximize her utility. The opportunity cost of one dollar spent on ice cream is the forgone utility of one dollar that could be on hamburger. The opportunity cost of one dollar spent on ice cream is the forgone utility of one dollar that could be on hamburger. If the utility of one additional dollar of ice cream is greater than the utility of the last dollar spent on hamburger, Jill can increase her total utility by spending one dollar less on hamburger and one dollar more one ice cream. If the utility of one additional dollar of ice cream is greater than the utility of the last dollar spent on hamburger, Jill can increase her total utility by spending one dollar less on hamburger and one dollar more one ice cream.
22
Hamburger or Hotdog If based on their perceived marginal utilities Jill values a hamburger four times as much as a hotdog, but the market price of a burger is eight times the price of a hotdog, she will buy a hotdog. That is because one dollar’s worth of hotdogs would give her more utility that one dollar’s worth of burgers. That is: If based on their perceived marginal utilities Jill values a hamburger four times as much as a hotdog, but the market price of a burger is eight times the price of a hotdog, she will buy a hotdog. That is because one dollar’s worth of hotdogs would give her more utility that one dollar’s worth of burgers. That is: MU D /P D > MU H /P H MU D /P D > MU H /P H
23
Utility Maximizing Rules A rational consumer would buy an additional unit of a good as long as the perceived dollar value of the utility of one additional unit of that good (say, its marginal dollar utility) is greater than its market price. A rational consumer would buy an additional unit of a good as long as the perceived dollar value of the utility of one additional unit of that good (say, its marginal dollar utility) is greater than its market price. The Two-Good Rule The Two-Good Rule MU I MU H MU I MU H --------- = ---------- --------- = ---------- $P I $P H $P I $P H
24
Utility Maximization under An Income constraint Consumers’ spending on consumer goods is constrained by their incomes: Consumers’ spending on consumer goods is constrained by their incomes: Income = Px Qx + Py Qy + Pw Ow + ….+Pz Qz While the consumer tries to equalize MUx/Px, MUy/ Py, MUw/Pw,………. and MUz/Pz, to maximize her utility her total spending cannot exceed her income. While the consumer tries to equalize MUx/Px, MUy/ Py, MUw/Pw,………. and MUz/Pz, to maximize her utility her total spending cannot exceed her income. For example, with an and income of $86 Jill is trying to decide how much ice cream and how much hamburger she should buy. Jill’s income = 5x10 + 6 x 6 = 86 Jill’s income = 5x10 + 6 x 6 = 86
25
Optimal Purchase Mix: Ice Cream and Hamburger
26
The Budget Line Income = Q I.P I + Q H.P H = (5 x 10)+(6 x 6) = 86 Ice Cream Hamburger o 8.6 14.33 5 6 86/10 86/6 Slope = P H /P I = 6/10 = 8.6/14.33 = 0.6
27
An Optimal Change Recall that to maximize utility a consumer would set: Recall that to maximize utility a consumer would set: (MUx/Px) = (MUy/Py) (MUx/Px) = (MUy/Py) If Px increases this equality would be disturbed: (MUx/Px) < (MUy/Py) If Px increases this equality would be disturbed: (MUx/Px) < (MUy/Py) To return to equality the consumer must adjust his/her consumption. (Have in mind that the consumer cannot change prices, and he/she has an income constraint.) To return to equality the consumer must adjust his/her consumption. (Have in mind that the consumer cannot change prices, and he/she has an income constraint.) What are the consumer’s options? What are the consumer’s options?
28
(MUx/Px) < (MUy/Py) In order to make the two sides of the above inequality equal again, given that Px and Py could not be changed, we would have to increase MUx and decrease MUy. Recalling the law of diminishing marginal utility, we can increase MUx by reducing X and decrease MUy by increasing Y. In order to make the two sides of the above inequality equal again, given that Px and Py could not be changed, we would have to increase MUx and decrease MUy. Recalling the law of diminishing marginal utility, we can increase MUx by reducing X and decrease MUy by increasing Y.
29
Price and the Shape of the Demand Curve The two effects of a price change: Income effect: Income effect: Normal good (-) Inferior goods (+) Substitution effect Substitution effect Buying less X and substituting it with Y until the optimizing condition is restored (-) Buying less X and substituting it with Y until the optimizing condition is restored (-) As Px increases, Qx decreases
30
Consumer Surplus The difference between what a consumer is willing to pay for an addition unit of a good and the market price that he/she actually pays is referred to as “consumer surplus”. The difference between what a consumer is willing to pay for an addition unit of a good and the market price that he/she actually pays is referred to as “consumer surplus”. The area between the demand curve and the price (line) measures the total consumer surplus. The area between the demand curve and the price (line) measures the total consumer surplus.
31
Consumer Surplus Price D Qx 0 P
32
Consumer Surplus Price D Qx 0 P D’ P’
33
An Alternative Approach to the Consumer Theory Indifference curves Indifference curves An indifference curve is a line drawn in a two- dimensional space showing different combinations of two goods from which the consumer draws the same amount of utility and therefore he/she is “indifferent” about. An indifference curve is a line drawn in a two- dimensional space showing different combinations of two goods from which the consumer draws the same amount of utility and therefore he/she is “indifferent” about. Budget lines Budget lines A budget line is a line drawn in a two-dimensional space representing a certain level of income with which the consumer can purchase various combinations of two goods at given prices. A budget line is a line drawn in a two-dimensional space representing a certain level of income with which the consumer can purchase various combinations of two goods at given prices.
34
Properties of Indifference curves Indifference curves for two “goods” are generally negatively sloped Indifference curves for two “goods” are generally negatively sloped The slope of an indifference curve reflects the degree of substitutability of two goods for one another The slope of an indifference curve reflects the degree of substitutability of two goods for one another Indifference curves are generally convex, reflecting the principle of diminishing returns Indifference curves are generally convex, reflecting the principle of diminishing returns Indifference curves never cross Indifference curves never cross Indifference curves that are farther from the origin represent higher levels of utility Indifference curves that are farther from the origin represent higher levels of utility Indifference curves for a “good” and a “bad” are positively sloped Indifference curves for a “good” and a “bad” are positively sloped
35
Indifference Curves X Y U1 U2 U3 U4 O Slope = Change in Y/Change in X = MUx/MUy
36
Budget Line X Y O Income = Px.Qx + Py. Qy I/Py I/Px Slope = Px/Py
37
Indifference Curves X Y U1 U2 U3 U4 O a b c d e MRS = MUx/MUy= Px/Py
38
A change in the price of X: Income and substitution effects X Y U1 U2 U3 U4 O a b c d e U5 C’ Xo X1 Yo Y1 c”
39
A change in the price of X: Income and substitution effects X Y U1 U2 U3 U4 O a b c d e U5 C’ Xo X1 Yo Y1 c”
Similar presentations
© 2024 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.