Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
1
UNIT II:Firms & Markets Theory of the Firm Profit Maximization Perfect Competition Review 7/15 MIDTERM 7/6
2
Perfect Competition Is it true that the rational pursuit of private interests produces coherence rather than chaos, and if so, how is it done? -- Frank Hahn Adam Smith described a world in which market competition weed-outs inefficient behavior, so that the ‘pursuit of private interests’ is led, as if by an invisible hand, to promote the general welfare of society. Today, we will solve for a competitive equilibrium and consider its welfare implications. We will also construct a general equilibrium model of Smith’s vision.
3
Perfect Competition Assumptions and Implications (from last time) Solving for the Competitive Equilibrium Equilibrium and Efficiency General Equilibrium Welfare Analysis
4
Perfect Competition Assumptions Firms are price-takers: can sell all the output they want at P*; can sell nothing at any price > P*. Homogenous product: e.g., wheat, t-shirts, long- distance phone minutes. Perfect factor mobility: in the long run, factors can move costlessly to where they are most productive (highest w, r). Perfect information: firms know everything about costs, consumer demand, other profitable opportunities, etc.
5
Perfect Competition Implications 1)Firms produce at minimum average cost, i.e., “efficient scale.” (AC = AC min ) 2)Price is equal to marginal cost. (P = MC) 3)Firms earn zero (economic) profits. ( = 0) 4)Market equilibrium is Pareto-efficient.
6
Perfect Competition In the Long-run… 1)Firms produce at minimum average cost, i.e., “efficient scale.” (AC = AC min ) 2)Price is equal to marginal cost. (P = MC) 3)Firms earn zero (economic) profits. ( = 0) 4)Market equilibrium is Pareto-efficient.
7
Perfect Competition The Short-run & the Long-run In the short-run, firms adjust to price signals by varying their utilization of labor (variable factors). In the long-run, firms adjust to profit signals by – varying plant size (fixed factors); and – entering or exiting the market. We can use this account to understand (and solve for) the long-run competitive equilibrium.
8
Short-run equilibrium with three firms. Firm A is making positive profits, Firm B is making zero profits, and Firm C is making negative profits (losses). Firm A Firm B Firm C q q q $P$P MC AC q: firm Q: market Perfect Competition
9
Short-run equilibrium with three firms. Firm A is making positive profits, Firm B is making zero profits, and Firm C is making negative profits (losses). Firm A Firm B Firm C q q q $P$P In the long run, Firm C will exit the market. MC AC MC AC Perfect Competition
10
In the long-run, inefficient firms will exit, and new firms will enter, as long as some firms are making positive economic profits. Firm A Firm B Firm D q q q $P$P MC AC MC AC Perfect Competition
11
In the long-run, if there are no barriers to entry, then new firms have access to the most efficient production technology. We call this the efficient scale. Firm A Firm D Firm E q* q q* q q* q $ P* MC AC MC AC Perfect Competition
12
Long-run equilibrium. Firms are producing at the efficient scale. P* = AC min ; = 0. $ P* q* q Q* Q $ LRS MC AC D Perfect Competition
13
Consider a perfectly competitive industry characterized by the following total cost and demand functions: TC = 100 + q 2 Q D = 1000 – 20P Find the market equilibrium in the long-run. How many firms are in the market?
14
Perfect Competition TC = 100 + q 2 Q D ’ = 1500 – 20P $ P* = 20 q* = 10 q Q** = 1100 Q $ LRS MC = 2q AVC = q AC = 100/q + q n = 110 D D’
15
Perfect Competition In the Long-run … 1)Firms produce at minimum average cost, i.e., “efficient scale.” 2)Price is equal to marginal cost. 3)Firms earn zero (economic) profits. 4)Market equilibrium is Pareto-efficient.
16
Equilibrium & Efficiency Is it true that the rational pursuit of private interests produces coherence rather than chaos, and if so, how is it done? -- Frank Hahn Equilibrium: most generally, an equilibrium is a state of the market in which decision plans are mutually consistent and therefore can be implemented. In the market, coordination takes place via prices: at a given price, all the output firms want to produce can be sold and all the goods consumers want to purchase can be bought.
17
Equilibrium & Efficiency Pareto Efficiency: an economic situation is Pareto efficient if no one can be made any better off without making someone else worse off. Pareto efficiency is a “good” thing, but it says nothing about equity; income distribution; economic justice. Competitive markets produce Pareto efficient equilibria (Q*), because at Q* the price someone is willing to pay for an additional unit of the good is equal to the price that someone must be paid to sell that unit.
18
Equilibrium & Efficiency The market equilibrium is Pareto efficient because at Q* the price someone is willing to pay for an additional unit of the good is equal to the price that someone must be paid to sell that unit. D Q Q* Q P At Q < Q*, a buyer and seller can exchange and both be better off Willing to pay P b P b = P s Willing to sell for P s S
19
Equilibrium & Efficiency We know that in a market equilibrium, both consumers and firms are optimizing, and we used these conditions to derive Demand and Supply curves. D: MRS = Px/Py S: MR = MC Q* Q P P o P* Consumer Surplus The total difference between what consumers are willing to pay and the market price CS = ½(P o - P*)Q* CS
20
Equilibrium & Efficiency We know that in a market equilibrium, both consumers and firms are optimizing, and we used these conditions to derive Demand and Supply curves. D: MRS = Px/Py S: MR = MC Q* Q P P o P* Producer Surplus The total difference between the firms’ marginal cost of production and the market price PS = (- FC) CS PS
21
Equilibrium & Efficiency We know that in a market equilibrium, both consumers and firms are optimizing, and we used these conditions to derive Demand and Supply curves. D: MRS = Px/Py S: MR = MC Q* Q P P o P* CS PS Social Surplus The sum of consumer and producer surplus SS = CS + PS Greatest at Q*
22
Pure Exchange An Edgeworth Box Indifference curves for Person 1. X Y 1
23
Pure Exchange An Edgeworth Box Indifference curves for Person 1 and Person 2. The dimensions of the box represent the total amounts of X and Y in the economy. 1 2 Y X
24
Pure Exchange An Edgeworth Box Contract Curve: the set of Pareto efficient allocations, where each person is at the highest possible indifference curve, given the indifference curve of the other person. 1 2 Y X
25
Pure Exchange An Edgeworth Box The initial endowment is shown in the graph, above. Both are better off at a point in the shaded area. 1 2 Y X Endowment
26
Pure Exchange An Edgeworth Box Exchange (trade) should occur until they reach a point on the contract curve. 1 2 Y X Endowment
27
Pure Exchange An Edgeworth Box 1 2 Y X Endowment Exchange (trade) should occur s.t., MRS 1 = MRS 2 = Px/Py.
28
Pure Exchange An Edgeworth Box 1 2 Y X Endowment Efficient Allocation Exchange leads to a Pareto Efficient Allocation.
29
General Equilibrium Consider an economy with 2 consumers and 1 producer. Despite their small numbers, all behave as price-takers. Consumers consume leisure (X) and widgets (W), and widgets require only labor (L) to produce, according to the following production function: W = L Consumers’ preferences are described by: U 1 = X 1 1/3 W 1 2/3 ; and U 2 = X 2 2/3 W 2 1/3 Also, L + X = 24 (hrs/day) and the wage (w) is $1/hr. Find: X 1,2, W 1,2, P
30
General Equilibrium Start by constructing the market demand curve W = W 1 + W 2 => W = 24/P w U 1 = X 1 1/3 W 1 2/3 U 2 = X 2 2/3 W 2 1/3 MU x = 1/3X -2/3 W 2/3 MU x = 2/3X -1/3 W 1/3 MU w = 2/3X 1/3 W -1/3 MU w = 1/3X 2/3 W -2/3 MRS 1 = W/(2X) = P x /P w MRS 2 = 2W/X = P x /P w P x =1=> X = 1/2P w W=> X = 2P w W BC: I= P x X + P w WBC: I= P x X + P w W 24 = 3/2 P w W 24 = 3P w W => W 1 = 16/P w => W 2 = 8/P w
31
General Equilibrium Now consider the firm’s problem: Profit ( = Total Revenue(TR) – Total Cost(TC) TR(Q) = PQ TC(Q) = rK + wL PPrice LLabor QQuantity KCapital w Wage Rate rRate on Capital
32
General Equilibrium Now consider the firm’s problem: Profit ( = Total Revenue(TR) – Total Cost(TC) TR = PW TC(Q) = rK + wL PPrice LLabor WWidgetsKCapital w Wage Rate rRate on Capital
33
General Equilibrium Now consider the firm’s problem: Profit ( = Total Revenue(TR) – Total Cost(TC) TR = PW TC(Q) = rK + wL MR = PMC = w since w =1, we know: P = 1; W = 24 W 1 = 16; W 2 = 8 X 1 = 8; X 2 = 16 also L + X = 24, so: L 1 = 16; L 2 = 8; L = 24 rRate on Capital From the Demand curve: W = 24/P w
34
General Equilibrium Now consider the firm’s problem: Profit ( = Total Revenue(TR) – Total Cost(TC) TR = PW TC(Q) = rK + wL MR = PMC = w since w =1, we know: P = 1; W = 24 W 1 = 16; W 2 = 8 X 1 = 8; X 2 = 16 also L + X = 24, so: L 1 = 16; L 2 = 8; L = 24 rRate on Capital
35
General Equilibrium The Market for Widgets rRate on Capital W* = 24 W P P*= 1 Demand: W = 24/P w Supply: P = 1
36
Welfare First Theorem of Welfare Economics: All competitive equilibria are Pareto-efficient. Second Theorem of Welfare Economics: Any allocation (of wealth or goods) can be sustained in a competitive equilibrium.
37
Welfare D = d Q P Demand Represents the horizontal sum of individual consumers’ demand curves d = consumer D = Market Demand We know that in a market equilibrium, both consumers and firms are optimizing, and we used these conditions to derive Demand and Supply curves.
38
Welfare We know that in a market equilibrium, both consumers and firms are optimizing, and we used these conditions to derive Demand and Supply curves. D: MRS = Px/Py Q P Demand Since all consumers are optimizing at the same output prices (Px/Py) MRS 1 = MRS 2 Consumption Efficiency d = consumer D = Market Demand
39
Welfare We know that in a market equilibrium, both consumers and firms are optimizing, and we used these conditions to derive Demand and Supply curves. D: MRS = Px/Py P = mc: MRTS = w/r Q* Q P P o P* Supply Represents individual firm’s optimal factor proportion, given factor prices (w/r) mc = individual firm’s marginal cost
40
Welfare We know that in a market equilibrium, both consumers and firms are optimizing, and we used these conditions to derive Demand and Supply curves. D: MRS = Px/Py P = mc: MRTS = w/r Q* Q P P o P* Supply Since all firms are optimizing (minimizing cost) at the same factor prices (w/r) MRTS x = MRTS y mc = individual firm’s marginal cost Production Efficiency
41
Welfare We know that in a market equilibrium, both consumers and firms are optimizing, and we used these conditions to derive Demand and Supply curves. D: MRS = Px/Py Q* Q P P o P* Supply Represents total marginal cost of production mc = firm’s S = Market Supply S = mc
42
Welfare We know that in a market equilibrium, both consumers and firms are optimizing, and we used these conditions to derive Demand and Supply curves. D: MRS = Px/Py Q* Q P P o P* Supply Represents marginal social cost of production mc = firm’s S = Market Supply S = MC
43
Welfare We know that in a market equilibrium, both consumers and firms are optimizing, and we used these conditions to derive Demand and Supply curves. D: MRS = Px/Py S: MR = MC Q* Q P P o P* Supply Since relative prices fully reflect relative costs MRS yx = MRT yx (MRT yx = MC x /MC y ) Product mix is optimal Marginal Rate of Transformation MRT yx = MC x /MC y Allocative Efficiency
44
Welfare Consumption Efficiency: All consumers are optimizing at given output prices (P x /P y ) MRS 1 = MRS 2 Production Efficiency: All firms are optimizing (minimizing cost) at given factor prices (w/r) MRTS x = MRTS y Allocation Efficiency: Product mix will be optimal; relative prices fully reflect relative costs MRS yx = MRT yx (where MRT yx = MC x /MC y )
45
Welfare The raison d'être of Welfare Economics is simple. How desirable it would be if we were able to pronounce as a matter of scientific demonstration that such and such a policy was good or bad(Robbins 1984, p. xx).
46
Next Time 7/8 Problem Set 2 due at start of class.
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.