Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

The one-factor Gaussian copula

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "The one-factor Gaussian copula"— Presentation transcript:

0 Intensity (and Variants) Gamma
Alan Stacey (joint work with Mark Joshi and carried out in large part at the Quantitative Research Centre (QuaRC), Royal Bank of Scotland) Credit Risk Under Lévy Models Edinburgh, September 22nd 2006

1 The one-factor Gaussian copula
The joint distribution of default times is determined from marginal distributions via a Gaussian copula. In the one-factor model, conditional on a single Gaussian random variable, Z, the default times are independent A single correlation number, , determines how much the default times are determined by the value of Z. If we restrict our attention to equity tranches, the map from  to price is strictly decreasing. So given the price of the 0 to x% equity tranche, there is a unique correlation (x%) which gives rise to this price. This is known as base correlation. The map, x→ (x), is the base correlation smile As usual, subject to recovery rate assumptions etc.

2 A standard but not a model
This has become the market standard for quoting correlation. The price of a tranche can be quoted as a spread, or as the value of  which would imply that spread. However, it is very hard to infer new prices within the Gaussian copula framework. Even arbitrage-free interpolation of the base correlation curve is very difficult. In practice fairly sophisticated interpolation and mapping methodologies have been developed to obtain prices. The model is not based on any financial explanation of why defaults are correlated – it just correlates default times in a naïve way. No dynamics. Just as with Black-Scholes, when there is a smile, a model is needed to give those prices, so that other things can be priced. But this situation is somewhat worse. The Black-Scholes model may be a good first approximation to market behaviour, but the Gaussian copula model is not a dynamic model at all. The mapping and interpolation methodologies may work directly with base correlation. But there seems to be general agreement that they are unsatisfactory.

3 Desiderata of a correlation model
Calibrates (more or less exactly) to relevant liquid market instruments: single name products (e.g. credit default swaps) quoted tranches of standardized baskets (iTraxx, CDX etc.) Deduce arbitrage-free prices of non-liquid instruments reasonably painlessly including tranches of standardized baskets with non-standard attachment points. bespoke CDOs with similar characteristics to an index hybrid CDOs, e.g. mix of regions or credit quality more general portfolio credit derivatives, e.g., CDO2

4 Desiderata (2) Realistic internal dynamics.
Stable Greeks with good P&L explanatory power leading to good hedges. Important market changes (e.g. spread widening) taking place with the model (and hence within-the-model Greek calculation)

5 The basic Intensity Gamma model
Based on stochastic or business time – the flow of information. If a lot happens in a given year then each firm has an increased chance of defaulting. One has an increasing business time process, t. Name i defaults with a constant hazard rate, ci, but defaults are driven by the business time process (common to all names) t, not calendar time. So conditional on the process (t), then for S ≤ T, the probability that a name survives to time T, given that it has survived to S, is exp(−ci(T− S)).

6 The gamma process We will take t to be stationary with independent increments. An increasing process with this property is known as a subordinator. The most well-known subordinator is the gamma process. Then t has a gamma distribution, with parameters t and  (for some ≥0, >0). This has density function It is helpful to think of this as the sum of t independent copies of an exponential random variable with parameter  (mean 1/). Of course, this is only strictly true when t is an integer. Stationarity is clearly desirable. One can argue about independent increments, depending on whether one thinks of this as a default process or genuinely an information process – we will return to this. The existence of a subordinator with this distribution for the increments needs to be proved. We do not go into this: look at a book on Levy processes. The gamma process is a pure jump process.

7 Calibrating to individual default probabilities
The unconditional survival probability to T of a name which defaults with business time hazard rate c is just a Laplace transform: E(−cT). If we take business time to be a gamma process, this is just So calibrating each ci to a survival probability for name i is immediate.

8 Refining the very basic model
For each name, we wish to match specified survival probabilities at a few different times. We take ci to be a piecewise constant function of calendar time. Note that if  in the specification of the gamma process changes, then each ci changes by the same factor. Effectively we have only one free parameter for the gamma process. We need more flexibility in our model for business time. For i=0,1, take (it) to be a gamma process with parameters i and i, the two processes being independent. Then set t = t0 + t1 + at for some constant drift a. We call this a multigamma process. And we call the model the intensity gamma model.

9 Pricing with intensity gamma
Given a choice of multigamma parameters we then rapidly calibrate each ci to the survival probabilities for name i at a small number of times. These are inferred from CDS prices (and a recovery rate assumption). A product whose payoff is determined by the default times of a basket of names can then be priced by Monte Carlo. Draw a random path for business time, (t). Conditional on (t), the default times for each name are independent. Draw each of these. Compute the payoff and discount, assuming deterministic interest rates. Average over many paths. Some deterministic recovery rate assumption, as is fairly standard practice, is implicit throughout. There is a a much better way to draw the time path than just inverting the distribution function for a gamma random variables. It involves finding the large jumps precisely and then approximating the remaining jumps by a constant drift.

10 Matching the correlation market
We aim to match the quoted prices of a single index. Prices are typically quoted for four or five tranches e.g. with detachment points 3%, 6%, 9%, 12%, 22%. Given multigamma parameters, we can price each tranche. We then find multigamma parameters which best match the market prices using an optimizer. Having chosen the multigamma parameters to match quoted tranche prices, we then use the same multigamma process for non-standard attachment/detachment points bespoke baskets with similar properties to the index to which we have calibrated: same region and similar levels of credit quality and diversity Significantly different maturities turn out to be more difficult. We think in terms of base correlation and equity tranches. We actually use the downhill simplex method. The calibration to the base correlation curve is the trickiest part of the process.

11 Matching an investment grade curve
The quality of fit we see here is typical of investment grade indices, whether European or North American, both before and after May.

12 North American High-Yield index
After May 2005, the high-yield curve became convex and non-monotonic. Unlike other market curves, it does not seem possible to fit this one perfectly with our multigamma model. However, the fit is still comfortably within bid-offer spread.

13 Extensions to the model (1)
Some products depend on a basket of names corresponding to different indices, e.g., High Yield/Investment Grade hybrids different regions. Divide the names of interest into sub-baskets corresponding to different indices. Calibrate a different multigamma processes to each index. The defaults of each sub-basket are driven by the corresponding multigamma process. One needs a way to make the different multigamma processes strongly correlated.

14 Extensions to the model (2)
Can introduce a random time lag between information arrival and default. This is more realistic. One way to do this is to have information arrive as a multigamma process, (t), as before, with the impact of the information spread out in a way that decays exponentially with parameter α. We then have a positive residual information process (Rt) satisfying and then an impact process, (It) driving defaults as before

15 Extensions to the model (3)
Retains tractability and rapid calibration to individual names with benefits including no longer have simultaneous defaults, although if there is a big jump in business time one will get a lot of defaults in a short space of time better matching of the market across different time horizons credit spread widening (one-factor only) within the model Can use a different class of subordinators, e.g. tempered stable processes.

16 Summary of strengths Provided one can match the index prices, one can obtain arbitrage-free prices for products whose payoffs depend upon the default times of a basket of names. These are consistent with Single-name survival probabilities (typically derived from CDSs) Tranche prices for the corresponding CDO index (and, to some extent, multiple indices where appropriate). Once calibrated to the appropriate index, pricing is rapid and straightforward. No ad hoc interpolation or curve-mapping techniques are required.

17 Some limitations Intensity Gamma is only a default model. It does not model the dynamics of credit spread movements. Within the model, credit spreads are deterministic. (In the time-lag extension, however, systemic movements of spreads do occur.) Hedging of spread movements must be outside-the-model. Similarly, the multigamma parameters are fixed, but if the index tranche prices move then they must be re-calibrated. Not capable of matching the market prices of correlation products with different maturities.

18 Disclaimer The views expressed in this report accurately reflect the personal views of Alan Stacey, the primary analyst(s) responsible for this report, about the subject securities or issuers referred to herein, and no part of such analyst(s)’ compensation was, is or will be directly or indirectly related to the specific recommendations or views expressed herein. Any reports referenced herein published after 14 April 2003 have been certified in accordance with Regulation AC. To obtain copies of these reports and their certifications, please contact Larry Pindyck ) or Valerie Monchi 44-(0) ). Lehman Brothers Inc. and any affiliate may have a position in the instruments or the Company discussed in this report. The Firm’s interests may conflict with the interests of an investor in those instruments. The research analysts responsible for preparing this report receive compensation based upon various factors, including, among other things, the quality of their work, firm revenues, including trading, competitive factors and client feedback. This material has been prepared and/or issued by Lehman Brothers Inc., member SIPC, and/or one of its affiliates ("Lehman Brothers") and has been approved by Lehman Brothers International (Europe), authorised and regulated by the Financial Services Authority, in connection with its distribution in the European Economic Area. This material is distributed in Japan by Lehman Brothers Japan Inc., and in Hong Kong by Lehman Brothers Asia Limited. This material is distributed in Australia by Lehman Brothers Australia Pty Limited, and in Singapore by Lehman Brothers Inc., Singapore Branch (“LBIS”). Where this material is distributed by LBIS, please note that it is intended for general circulation only and the recommendations contained herein do not take into account the specific investment objectives, financial situation or particular needs of any particular person. An investor should consult his Lehman Brothers’ representative regarding the suitability of the product and take into account his specific investment objectives, financial situation or particular needs before he makes a commitment to purchase the investment product. This material is distributed in Korea by Lehman Brothers International (Europe) Seoul Branch. This document is for information purposes only and it should not be regarded as an offer to sell or as a solicitation of an offer to buy the securities or other instruments mentioned in it. No part of this document may be reproduced in any manner without the written permission of Lehman Brothers. We do not represent that this information, including any third party information, is accurate or complete and it should not be relied upon as such. It is provided with the understanding that Lehman Brothers is not acting in a fiduciary capacity. Opinions expressed herein reflect the opinion of Lehman Brothers and are subject to change without notice. The products mentioned in this document may not be eligible for sale in some states or countries, and they may not be suitable for all types of investors. If an investor has any doubts about product suitability, he should consult his Lehman Brothers representative. The value of and the income produced by products may fluctuate, so that an investor may get back less than he invested. Value and income may be adversely affected by exchange rates, interest rates, or other factors. Past performance is not necessarily indicative of future results. If a product is income producing, part of the capital invested may be used to pay that income. Lehman Brothers may, from time to time, perform investment banking or other services for, or solicit investment banking or other business from any company mentioned in this document. © 2005 Lehman Brothers. All rights reserved. Additional information is available on request. Please contact a Lehman Brothers entity in your home jurisdiction.


Download ppt "The one-factor Gaussian copula"

Similar presentations


Ads by Google