Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

A State-Centered Approach to the Politics of Trade

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "A State-Centered Approach to the Politics of Trade"— Presentation transcript:

1 A State-Centered Approach to the Politics of Trade
READING ASSIGNMENT: Oatley – Chapter 5

2 Plan What does the state want? Why would the state intervene? Survival
Infant Industries

3 What does the state want?
Improve overall welfare Increase its relative power

4 What does the state want?
SURVIVAL! Political Institutions shape the incentives of political leaders Under democracy, leaders survive by winning votes Under dictatorship, leaders survive by satisfying elite constituents: military, big business, foreign interests

5

6 Democracy vs. Dictatorship

7 Hazard Rate over Time for Democracies (Solid Line) & Dictatorships (Dotted Line) – Time in years

8 Time in office Does *not* improve a democratic leader’s chances in office What then helps democratic leaders survive? PROVISION OF “PUBLIC GOODS” In the United States: Economic Growth

9 Time in office *Does* improve an autocratic leader’s chances in office
Why? PROVISION OF “PRIVATE GOODS” Pay off a small, loyal group of supporters Military elites Business elites

10 Changing focus to A more specific institution: Legislative Representation
Proportional? Or Malapportioned?

11 Who needs the most gasoline per capita? Urban v Rural

12 Policy outcome? We’ve got Interests & Incentives
Now, to get the policy outcome,… We interact interests/incentives with a domestic political institution: Malapportionment!

13 Malapportionment tends to weigh RURAL preferences more than URBAN
(i.e., Proportional representation tends to weigh URBAN preferences more than RURAL) Does this have an effect on NATIONAL policy?

14 Test: Does malapportionment affect: Gasoline prices

15

16 How can the state get what it wants?
Industrial Policy Tariffs Subsidies Investment

17 Why does the state protect?
One answer: Infant industries

18 Infant-industry case Long-run welfare gains created by a new industry will be greater than the short-run losses of social welfare “infant” industries – like children who need the “protection” of their parents until they grow strong Comparative advantages are DYNAMIC

19 Both states are better off with trade…BUT
Would you rather live in Brazil with trade? Or the United States with autarky?

20 Infant Industry Argument 1: Fixed costs & Economies of scale
Economies of scale refers to the decreased per-unit-cost as output increases. The initial investment of capital is diffused (spread) over an increasing number of units of output  The marginal cost of producing a good or service decreases as production increases

21 Example Suppose an industry requires an initial investment (fixed cost) of $1000 With 100 customers, the Average Fixed Cost is $10 With 200 customers, the Average Fixed Cost becomes $5 This results in a lower average total cost

22 Diseconomies of scale:
No economies of scale: If costs increase proportionately to the quantity of all input factors Diseconomies of scale: If costs increase by a greater amount than the quantity of all input factors Economies of scale: If costs decrease by a greater amount than the quantity of all input factors

23 A different way to approach “returns to scale”
Where all inputs increase by a factor of 2, new values for output should be: Twice the previous output = ? a constant return to scale More than twice the previous output = ? an increased return to scale Less than twice the previous output = ? a decreased return to scale

24 Formal notation Y is output, K is capital, L is labor, F is the production function: Y=F(K,L) Suppose we double our inputs: 2K, 2L F(2K,2L) = ??? How much does Y increase? If F(2K,2L) = 2F(K,L)  We have _______ returns to scale CONSTANT F(2K,2L) > 2F(K,L)  We have _______ returns to scale INCREASING If F(2K,2L) < 2F(K,L)  We have _______ returns to scale DECREASING

25 Slightly more abstract notation
Y is output, K is capital, L is labor, F is the production function, a is the increase in inputs Y=F(K,L) If F(aK,aL)=aF(K,L)  Constant returns to scale If F(aK,aL)>aF(K,L)  Increasing returns to scale F(aK,aL)<aF(K,L)  Decreasing returns to scale For fun: Apply this to the “Cobb-Douglas” production function! Yippee!

26 Bringing the two sets of concepts together?
Y=F(K,L) + start up costs You can have increasing returns to scale if… And/or if investments in inputs generate disproportionately high increases in outputs Start-up costs are high

27 Infant Industry Argument 2: Economies of experience
Efficient production requires specific skills that can only be acquired through production in the industry Experienced management Skilled workers Network of suppliers

28 Why can’t markets efficiently educate / train the workforce?
Trained people may leave the firm, taking their skills elsewhere Missing market: “Futures market for labor” Externalities from education?

29 Economies of scale &/or experience can lead to:
Oligopoly, market power Barriers to entry First mover advantages

30 Suppose an industry where market-demand supports only one firm (high tech – e.g., aircraft)
European firm PRODUCE NOT PRODUCE – 5, – 5 100, 0 0, 100 0, 0 US firm What are the two EQUILIBRIA? (R,C)

31 Equilibrium: An outcome where no player has an incentive to deviate from his or her chosen strategy given the strategies of the other players.

32 Whoever moves first wins!

33 Now suppose the US moved first, but Europe offers a subsidy… (R,C)
European firm PRODUCE NOT PRODUCE – 5, 5 100, 0 0, 110 0, 0 US firm

34 Take-aways What do governments want? Survival Democracy v. Autocracy
Malapportionment Why does the state intervene? Infant Industries Economies of Scale Increasing returns to scale Economies of experience First mover advantages Equilibria

35 Thank you WE ARE GLOBAL GEORGETOWN!


Download ppt "A State-Centered Approach to the Politics of Trade"

Similar presentations


Ads by Google