Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published byStuart Gardner Modified over 9 years ago
1
Asymmetric Information Snyder and Nicholson, Copyright ©2008 by Thomson South-Western. All rights reserved.
2
Asymmetric Information Transactions can involve a considerable amount of uncertainty –can lead to inefficiency when one side has better information The side with better information is said to have private information or asymmetric information
3
The Value of Contracts Contractual provisions can be added in order to circumvent some of the inefficiencies associated with asymmetric information –rarely do they eliminate them
4
Principal-Agent Model The party who proposes the contract is called the principal The party who decides whether or not to accept the contract and then performs under the terms of the contract is the agent –typically the party with asymmetric information
5
Leading Models Two models of asymmetric information –the agent’s actions affect the principal, but the principal does not observe the actions directly called a hidden-action model or a moral hazard model –the agent has private information before signing the contract (his type) called a hidden-type model or an adverse selection model
6
First, Second, and Third Best In a full-information environment, the principal could propose a contract that maximizes joint surplus –could capture all of the surplus for himself, leaving the agent just enough to make him indifferent between agreeing to the contract or not This is called a first-best contract
7
First, Second, and Third Best The contract that maximizes the principal’s surplus subject to the constraint that he is less well informed than the agent is called a second-best contract Adding further constraints leads to the third best, fourth best, etc.
8
Hidden Actions The principal would like the agent to take an action that maximizes their joint surplus But, the agent’s actions may be unobservable to the principal –the agent will prefer to shirk Contracts can mitigate shirking by tying compensation to observable outcomes
9
Hidden Actions Often, the principal is more concerned with outcomes than actions anyway –may as well condition the contract on outcomes
10
Hidden Actions The problem is that the outcome may depend in part on random factors outside of the agent’s control –tying the agent’s compensation to outcomes exposes the agent to risk –if the agent is risk averse, he may require the payment of a risk premium before he will accept the contract
11
Owner-Manager Relationship Suppose a firm has one representative owner and one manager –the owner offers a contract to the manager –the manager decides whether to accept the contract and what action e 0 to take an increase in e increases the firm’s gross profit but is personally costly to the manager
12
Owner-Manager Relationship The firm’s gross profit is g = e + –where represents demand, cost, and other economic factors outside of the agent’s control assume ~ (0, 2 ) –c(e) is the manager’s personal disutility from effort assume c’(e) > 0 and c’’(e) < 0
13
Owner-Manager Relationship If s is the manager’s salary, the firm’s net profit is n = n – s The risk-neutral owner wishes to maximize the expected value of profit E( n ) = E(e + – s) = e – E(s)
14
Owner-Manager Relationship We will assume the manager is risk averse with a constant risk aversion parameter of A > 0 The manager’s expected utility will be
15
First-Best With full information, it is relatively easy to design an optimal salary contract –the owner can pay the manager a salary if he exerts a first-best level of effort and nothing otherwise –for the manager to accept the contract E(u) = s* - c(e*) 0
16
First-Best The owner will pay the lowest salary possible [s* = c(e*)] The owner’s net profit will be E( n ) = e* - E(s*) = e* - c(e*) –at the optimum, the marginal cost of effort equals the marginal benefit
17
Second Best If the owner cannot observe effort, the contract cannot be conditioned on e –the owner may still induce effort if some of the manager’s salary depends on gross profit –suppose the owner offers a salary such as s( g ) = a + b g –a is the fixed salary and b is the power of the incentive scheme
18
Second Best This relationship can be viewed as a three-stage game –owner sets the salary (choosing a and b) –the manager decides whether or not to accept the contract –the manager decides how much effort to put forth (conditional on accepting the contract)
19
Second Best Because the owner cannot observe e directly and the manager is risk-averse, the second-best effort will be less than the first-best effort –the risk premium adds to the owner’s cost of inducing effort
20
First- versus Second-Best Effort e e** MB 1 e*e* MC in first best c’(e) The owner’s MC is higher in the second best, leading to lower effort by the manager MC in second best c’(e) + risk term
21
Moral Hazard in Insurance If a person is fully insured, he will have a reduced incentive to undertake precautions –may increase the likelihood of a loss occurring
22
Moral Hazard in Insurance The effect of insurance coverage on an individual’s precautions, which may change the likelihood or size of losses, is known as moral hazard
23
Mathematical Model Suppose a risk-averse individual faces the possibility of a loss ( l ) that will reduce his initial wealth (W 0 ) –the probability of loss is –an individual can reduce this probability by spending more on preventive measures (e)
24
Mathematical Model An insurance company offers a contract involving a payment of x to the individual if a loss occurs –the premium is p If the individual takes the coverage, his expected utility is E[u(W)] = (1- )u(W 0 -e-p) + ( )u(W 0 -e-p-l+x)
25
First-Best Insurance Contract In the first-best case, the insurance company can perfectly monitor e –should set the terms to maximize its expected profit subject to the participation constraint the expected utility with insurance must be at least as large as the utility without the insurance –will result in full insurance with x = l –the individual will choose the socially efficient level of precaution
26
Second-Best Insurance Contract Assume the insurance company cannot monitor e at all –an incentive compatibility constraint must be added The second-best contract will typically not involve full insurance –exposing the individual to some risk induces him to take some precaution
27
Hidden Types In the hidden-type model, the individual has private information about an innate characteristic he cannot choose –the agent’s private information at the time of signing the contract puts him in a better position
28
Hidden Types The principal will try to extract as much surplus as possible from agents through clever contract design –include options targeted to every agent type
29
Nonlinear Pricing Consider a monopolist who sells to a consumer with private information about his own valuation for the good The monopolist offers a nonlinear price schedule –menu of different-sized bundles at different prices –larger bundles sell for lower per-unit price
30
Mathematical Model Suppose a single consumer obtains surplus from consuming a bundle of q units for which he pays a total tariff of T u = v(q) – T –assume that v’(q) > 0 and v’’(q) < 0 –the consumer’s type is H is the “high” type (with probability of ) L is the “low” type (with probability of 1- ) 0 < L < H
31
Mathematical Model Suppose the monopolist has a constant average and marginal cost of c The monopolist’s profit from selling q units is = T – cq
32
First-Best Nonlinear Pricing In the first-best case, the monopolist observes At the optimum v’(q) = c –the marginal social benefit of increased quantity is equal to the marginal social cost
33
First-Best Nonlinear Pricing q T U0LU0L This graph shows the consumers’ indifference curves (by type) and the firm’s isoprofit curves U0HU0H
34
First-Best Nonlinear Pricing q T A U0LU0L A is the first-best contract offered to the “high” type and B is the first-best offer to the “low” type U0HU0H B
35
Second-Best Nonlinear Pricing Suppose the monopolist cannot observe –knows the distribution Choosing A is no longer incentive compatible for the high type –the monopolist must reduce the high-type’s tariff
36
Second-Best Nonlinear Pricing q T A U0LU0L The “high” type can reach a higher indifference curve by choosing B U0HU0H B U2HU2H To keep him from choosing B, the monopolist must reduce the “high” type’s tariff by offering a point like C C
37
Second-Best Nonlinear Pricing q T A U0LU0L The monopolist can also alter the “low” type’s bundle to make it less attractive to the high type U0HU0H B U2HU2H C D E q** H q** L
38
Monopoly Coffee Shop The college has a single coffee shop –faces a marginal cost of 5 cents per ounce The representative customer faces an equal probability of being one of two types –a coffee hound ( H = 20) –a regular Joe ( L = 15) Assume v(q) = 2q 0.5
39
First Best Substituting such that marginal cost = marginal benefit, we get q = ( /c) 2 q* L = 9 q* H = 16 T* L = 90 T* H = 160 E( ) = 62.5
40
Incentive Compatibility when Types Are Hidden The first-best pricing scheme is not incentive compatible if the monopolist cannot observe type –keeping the cup sizes the same, the price for the large cup would have to be reduced by 30 cents –the shop’s expected profit falls to 47.5
41
Second Best The shop can do better by reducing the size of the small cup The size that is second best would be L q L -0.5 = c + ( H - L )q L -0.5 q** L = 4 T** L = 60 E( ) = 50
42
Adverse Selection in Insurance Adverse selection is a problem facing insurers where the risky types are more likely to accept an insurance policy and are more expensive to serve –assume policy holders may be one of two types H = high risk L = low risk
43
First Best The insurer can observe the individual’s risk type First best involves full insurance –different premiums are charged to each type to extract all surplus
44
First Best certainty line W1W1 W2W2 U0LU0L Without insurance each type finds himself at E U0HU0H A B E A and B represent full insurance
45
Second Best If the insurer cannot observe type, first- best contracts will not be incentive compatible –if the insurer offered A and B, the high-risk type would choose B –the insurer must change the coverage offered to low-risk individuals to make it unattractive to high-risk individuals
46
First Best certainty line W1W1 W2W2 U0LU0L U0HU0H A B E U1HU1H The high-risk type is fully insured, but his premium is higher (than it would be at B) C The low-risk type is only partially insured D
47
Market Signaling If the informed player moves first, he can “signal” his type to the other party –the low-risk individual would benefit from providing his type to insurers he should be willing to pay the difference between his equilibrium and his first-best surplus to issue such a signal
48
Market for Lemons Sellers of used cars have more information on the condition of the car –but the act of offering the car for sale can serve as a signal of car quality it must be below some threshold that would have induced the owner to keep it
49
Market for Lemons Suppose there is a continuum of qualities from low-quality lemons to high-quality gems –only the owner knows a car’s type Because buyers cannot determine the quality, all used cars sell for the same price –function of average car quality
50
Market for Lemons A car’s owner will choose to keep a car that is in the upper end of the spectrum –reduces the average quality –reduces the market price –leads sellers of the high end of the remaining cars to keep their cars reduces average quality and market price
51
Adverse Selection Consider a used car market. Two types of cars; “lemons” and “peaches”. Each lemon seller will accept $1,000; a buyer will pay at most $1,200. Each peach seller will accept $2,000; a buyer will pay at most $2,400.
52
Adverse Selection If every buyer can tell a peach from a lemon, then lemons sell for between $1,000 and $1,200, and peaches sell for between $2,000 and $2,400. Gains-to-trade are generated when buyers are well informed.
53
Adverse Selection Suppose no buyer can tell a peach from a lemon before buying. What is the most a buyer will pay for any car?
54
Adverse Selection Let q be the fraction of peaches. 1 - q is the fraction of lemons. Expected value to a buyer of any car is at most
55
Adverse Selection Suppose EV > $2000. Every seller can negotiate a price between $2000 and $EV (no matter if the car is a lemon or a peach). All sellers gain from being in the market.
56
Adverse Selection Suppose EV < $2000. A peach seller cannot negotiate a price above $2000 and will exit the market. So all buyers know that remaining sellers own lemons only. Buyers will pay at most $1200 and only lemons are sold.
57
Adverse Selection Hence “too many” lemons “crowd out” the peaches from the market. Gains-to-trade are reduced since no peaches are traded. The presence of the lemons inflicts an external cost on buyers and peach owners.
58
Adverse Selection How many lemons can be in the market without crowding out the peaches? Buyers will pay $2000 for a car only if
59
Adverse Selection How many lemons can be in the market without crowding out the peaches? Buyers will pay $2000 for a car only if So if over one-third of all cars are lemons, then only lemons are traded.
60
Adverse Selection A market equilibrium in which both types of cars are traded and cannot be distinguished by the buyers is a pooling equilibrium. A market equilibrium in which only one of the two types of cars is traded, or both are traded but can be distinguished by the buyers, is a separating equilibrium.
61
Adverse Selection What if there is more than two types of cars? Suppose that car quality is Uniformly distributed between $1000 and $2000 any car that a seller values at $x is valued by a buyer at $(x+300). Which cars will be traded?
62
Adverse Selection The expected value of any car to a buyer is $1500 + $300 = $1800. 100020001500 Seller values So sellers who value their cars at more than $1800 exit the market.
63
Adverse Selection 10001800 The distribution of values of cars remaining on offer Seller values
64
Adverse Selection 100018001400 The expected value of any remaining car to a buyer is $1400 + $300 = $1700. So now sellers who value their cars between $1700 and $1800 exit the market. Seller values
65
Adverse Selection Where does this unraveling of the market end? Let v H be the highest seller value of any car remaining in the market. The expected seller value of a car is
66
Adverse Selection So a buyer will pay at most This must be the price which the seller of the highest value car remaining in the market will just accept; i.e.
67
Adverse Selection Adverse selection drives out all cars valued by sellers at more than $1600.
68
Signaling Adverse selection is an outcome of an informational deficiency. What if information can be improved by high-quality sellers signaling credibly that they are high-quality? E.g. warranties, professional credentials, references from previous clients etc.
69
Signaling A labor market has two types of workers; high-ability and low-ability. A high-ability worker’s marginal product is a H. A low-ability worker’s marginal product is a L. a L < a H. A fraction h of all workers are high-ability. 1 - h is the fraction of low-ability workers.
70
Signaling Each worker is paid his expected marginal product. If firms knew each worker’s type they would pay each high-ability worker w H = a H pay each low-ability worker w L = a L.
71
Signaling If firms cannot tell workers’ types then every worker is paid the (pooling) wage rate; i.e. the expected marginal product w P = (1 - h)a L + ha H.
72
Signaling w P = (1 - h)a L + ha H < a H, the wage rate paid when the firm knows a worker really is high-ability. So high-ability workers have an incentive to find a credible signal.
73
Signaling Workers can acquire “education”. Education costs a high-ability worker c H per unit and costs a low-ability worker c L per unit. c L > c H. Suppose that education has no effect on workers’ productivities; i.e., the cost of education is a deadweight loss.
74
Signaling High-ability workers will acquire e H education units if (i) w H - w L = a H - a L > c H e H, and (ii) w H - w L = a H - a L < c L e H. (i) says acquiring e H units of education benefits high-ability workers. (ii) says acquiring e H education units hurts low-ability workers.
75
Signaling and together require Acquiring such an education level credibly signals high-ability, allowing high-ability workers to separate themselves from low-ability workers.
76
Signaling Q: Given that high-ability workers acquire e H units of education, how much education should low-ability workers acquire? A: Zero. Low-ability workers will be paid w L = a L so long as they do not have e H units of education and they are still worse off if they do.
77
Signaling Signaling can improve information in the market. But, total output did not change and education was costly so signaling worsened the market’s efficiency. So improved information need not improve gains-to-trade.
78
Auctions A seller can often do better if several buyers compete against each other –high-value consumers are pushed to bid high Different formats may lead to different outcomes –sellers should think carefully about how to design the auction
79
First-Price Sealed Auction Bid All bidders simultaneously submit secret bids The auctioneer unseals the bids and awards the object to the highest bidder The highest bidder pays his own bid
80
First-Price Sealed Auction Bid In equilibrium, it is a weakly dominated strategy to submit a bid b greater than or equal to the buyer’s valuation v –a strategy is weakly dominated if there is another strategy that does at least as well against all rivals’ strategies and strictly better against at least one
81
First-Price Sealed Auction Bid A buyer receives no surplus if he bids b=v no matter what his rivals bid –by bidding b < v, there is a chance for some positive surplus Since players likely avoid weakly dominated strategies, we can expect bids to be lower then buyers’ valuations
82
Second-Price Sealed Auction Bid The highest bidder pays the next highest bid rather than his own All bidding strategies are weakly dominated by the strategy of bidding exactly one’s valuation –second-price auctions induce bidders to reveal their valuations
83
Second-Price Sealed Auction Bid The reason that bidding one’s valuation is weakly dominant is that the winner’s bid does not affect the amount he has to pay –that depends on someone else’s bid
84
Common Values Auctions In complicated economic environments, different auction formats do not necessarily yield the same revenue Suppose the good has the same value to all bidders, but they do ot know exactly what that value is –common values auction
85
Common Values Auctions The winning bidder realizes that every other bidder probably though the object was worth less –means that he probably overestimated the value when bidding This is often referred to as the winner’s curse
86
Important Points to Note: Asymmetric information is often studied using a principal-agent model in which a principal offers a contract to an agent who has private information –the two main variants of the model are the models of hidden actions and hidden types
87
Important Points to Note: In a hidden-action model (called a moral hazard model), the principal tries to induce the agent to take appropriate actions by tying the agent’s payments to observable outcomes –doing so exposes the agent to random fluctuations, which is costly for a risk- averse agent
88
Important Points to Note: In a hidden-type model (called an adverse selection model), the principal cannot extract all of the surplus from high types because they can always gain positive surplus by pretending to be a low type –the principal will offer a menu of contracts from which different types of agents can select
89
Important Points to Note: In a hidden-type model, the principal will offer a menu of contracts from which different types of agents can select –the principal distorts the quantity offered to low types in order to make the contract less attractive to high types
90
Important Points to Note: Most of the insights gained from the basic form of a principal-agent model, in which the principal is a monopolist, carry over to the case of competing principals –the main change is that agents obtain more surplus
91
Important Points to Note: The lemons problem arises when sellers have private information about the quality of their goods –sellers whose goods are higher than average quality may refrain from selling –the market may collapse, with goods of only the lowest quality being offered for sale
92
Important Points to Note: The principal can extract more surplus from agents if several of them are pitted against one another in an auction setting –in a simple economic environment, a variety of common auction formats generate the same revenue –differences in auction format may generate different levels of revenue in more complicated settings
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.