Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published byLouise Barnett Modified over 9 years ago
2
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Exercise 9.6 MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell February 2007
3
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Ex 9.6(1): Question purpose: to derive equilibrium prices and incomes as a function of endowment. To show the limits to redistribution within the GE model for a alternative SWFs purpose: to derive equilibrium prices and incomes as a function of endowment. To show the limits to redistribution within the GE model for a alternative SWFs method: find price-taking optimising demands for each of the two types, use these to compute the excess demand function and solve for method: find price-taking optimising demands for each of the two types, use these to compute the excess demand function and solve for
4
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Ex 9.6(1): budget constraints Use commodity 2 as numéraire Use commodity 2 as numéraire price of good 1 is price of good 2 is 1 Evaluate incomes for the two types, given their resources: Evaluate incomes for the two types, given their resources: type a has endowment (30, k) therefore y a = 30 + k type b has endowment (60, 210 k) therefore y b = 60 + [210 k] Budget constraints for the two types are therefore: Budget constraints for the two types are therefore: x 1 a + x 2 a ≤ 30 + k x 1 b + x 2 b ≤ 60 + [210 k]
5
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Ex 9.6(1): optimisation We could jump straight to a solution We could jump straight to a solution utility functions are simple… …so we can draw on known results Cobb-Douglas preferences imply Cobb-Douglas preferences imply indifference curves do not touch the origin… …so we need consider only interior solutions also demand functions for the two commodities exhibit constant expenditure shares In this case (for type a) In this case (for type a) coefficients of Cobb-Douglas are 2 and 1 so expenditure shares are ⅔ and ⅓ (and for b they will be ⅓ and ⅔ ) gives the optimal demands immediately… Jump to “equilibrium price”
6
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Ex 9.6(1): optimisation, type a The Lagrangean is: The Lagrangean is: 2log x 1 a + log x 2 a + a [y a x 1 a x 2 a ] where a is the Lagrange multiplier and y a is 30 + k FOC for an interior solution FOC for an interior solution 2/x 1 a a = 0 1/x 2 a a = 0 y a x 1 a x 2 a = 0 Eliminating a from these three equations, demands are: Eliminating a from these three equations, demands are: x 1 a = ⅔ y a / x 2 a = ⅓ y a
7
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Ex 9.6(1): optimisation, type b The Lagrangean is: The Lagrangean is: log x 1 b + 2log x 2 b + b [y b x 1 b x 2 b ] where b is the Lagrange multiplier and y b is 60 + 210 k FOC for an interior solution FOC for an interior solution 1/x 1 b b = 0 2/x 2 b b = 0 y b x 1 b x 2 b = 0 Eliminating b from these three equations, demands are: Eliminating b from these three equations, demands are: x 1 b = ⅓ y b / x 2 b = ⅔y b
8
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Ex 9.6(1): equilibrium price Take demand equations for the two types Take demand equations for the two types substitute in the values for income type-a demand becomes type-b demand becomes Excess demand for commodity 2: Excess demand for commodity 2: [10 + ⅓k]+[40 +140 − ⅔k] − 210 which simplifies to 50 − ⅓k − 70 Set excess demand to 0 for equilibrium: Set excess demand to 0 for equilibrium: equilibrium price must be: = [210 + k] / 150
9
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Ex 9.6(2): Question and solution Incomes for the two types are resources: Incomes for the two types are resources: y a = 30 + k y b = 60 + [210 k] The equilibrium price is: The equilibrium price is: = [210 + k] / 150 So we can solve for incomes as: So we can solve for incomes as: y a = [210 + 6k] / 5 y b = [1470 3k] / 5 Equivalently we can write y a and y b in terms of as Equivalently we can write y a and y b in terms of as y a = 180 210 y b = 420 90
10
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Ex 9.6(3): Question purpose: to use the outcome of the GE model to plot the “income- possibility” set purpose: to use the outcome of the GE model to plot the “income- possibility” set method: plot incomes corresponding to extremes of allocating commodity 2, namely k = 0 and k = 210. Then fill in the gaps. method: plot incomes corresponding to extremes of allocating commodity 2, namely k = 0 and k = 210. Then fill in the gaps.
11
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Income possibility set yaya ybyb 0 200 300 100200 300 100 (42, 294) (294, 168) incomes for k = 0 incomes for k = 210 incomes for intermediate values of k attainable set if income can be thrown away y b = 315 ½y a
12
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Ex 9.6(4): Question purpose: find a welfare optimum subject to the “income-possibility” set purpose: find a welfare optimum subject to the “income-possibility” set method: plot contours for the function W on the previous diagram. method: plot contours for the function W on the previous diagram.
13
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Welfare optimum: first case yaya ybyb 0 200 300 100200 300 100 income possibility set Contours of W = log y a + log y b Maximisation of W over income- possibility set W is maximised at corner incomes are (294, 168) here k = 210 so optimum is where all of resource 2 is allocated to type a
14
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Ex 9.6(5): Question purpose: as in part 4 purpose: as in part 4 method: as in part 4 method: as in part 4
15
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Welfare optimum: second case yaya ybyb 0 200 300 100200 300 100 income possibility set Contours of W = y a + y b Maximisation of W over income- possibility set again W is maximised at corner …where k = 210 so optimum is where all of resource 2 is allocated to type a
16
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Ex 9.6: Points to note Applying GE methods gives the feasible set Limits to redistribution natural bounds on k asymmetric attainable set Must take account of corners Get the same W-maximising solution where society is averse to inequality where society is indifferent to inequality
Similar presentations
© 2024 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.