Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published bySharlene Porter Modified over 9 years ago
1
Chapter Thirty-Five Information Technology
2
Information Technologies The crucial ideas are: Complementarity Network externality
3
Information Technologies; Complementarity Definition: Commodity A complements commodity B if more of commodity A increases the value of an extra unit of commodity B. More software increases the value of a computer. More roads increase the value of a car.
4
Information Technologies; Network Externality Definition: A commodity has a positive (negative) network externality if the utility to a consumer of that commodity increases (decreases) as more people also consume the commodity. Email gives more utility to any one user if more other people use email. A highway gives less utility to any one user as more people use it (congestion).
5
Complementarity Information technologies have increased greatly the complementarities between commodities. Computers and operating systems (OS). DVD players and DVD disks. WiFi sites and laptop computers. Cell phones and cell phone towers.
6
Complementarity How should a firm behave when it produces a commodity that complements another commodity? The problem is: When you make more of your product (commodity A) you increase the value of firm B’s product (commodity B). Can you get for yourself some of gain you create for firm B?
7
Complementarity An obvious strategy is for firms A and B to cooperate somewhat with each other. Microsoft releases part of its OS to firms making software that runs under its OS. DVD manufacturers agree upon a standard format for their disks.
8
Complementarity The price of a computer is p C. The price of the OS is p OS. The quantities demanded of computers and the OS depends upon p C + p OS, not just p C or just p OS.
9
Complementarity The price of a computer is p C. The price of the OS is p OS. The quantities demanded of computers and the OS depends upon p C + p OS, not just p C or just p OS. Suppose the computer and software firms’ marginal production costs are zero. Fixed costs are F C and F OS.
10
Complementarity Suppose the firms do not collude. The computer firm’s problem is: choose p C to maximize p C D(p C + p OS ) – F C. The OS firm’s problem is: choose p OS to maximize p OS D(p C + p OS ) – F OS.
11
Complementarity Suppose the firms do not collude. The computer firm’s problem is: choose p C to maximize p C D(p C + p OS ) – F C. The OS firm’s problem is: choose p OS to maximize p OS D(p C + p OS ) – F OS. Assume D(p C + p OS ) = a – b(p C + p OS ).
12
Complementarity The computer firm’s problem is: choose p C to maximize p C (a – b(p C + p OS )) – F C. The OS firm’s problem is: choose p OS to maximize p OS (a – b(p C + p OS )) – F OS.
13
Complementarity Choose p C to maximize p C (a – b(p C + p OS )) – F C p C = (a – bp OS )/2b. (C) Choose p OS to maximize p OS (a – b(p C + p OS )) – F OS p OS = (a – bp C )/2b. (OS)
14
Complementarity Choose p C to maximize p C (a – b(p C + p OS )) – F C p C = (a – bp OS )/2b. (C) Choose p OS to maximize p OS (a – b(p C + p OS )) – F OS p OS = (a – bp C )/2b. (OS) A NE is a pair (p* C,p* OS ) solving (C) and (OS).
15
Complementarity Choose p C to maximize p C (a – b(p C + p OS )) – F C p C = (a – bp OS )/2b. (C) Choose p OS to maximize p OS (a – b(p C + p OS )) – F OS p OS = (a – bp C )/2b. (OS) A NE is a pair (p* C,p* OS ) solving (C) and (OS). p* C = p* OS = a/3b.
16
Complementarity p* C = p* OS = a/3b. When the firms do not cooperate the price of a computer with an OS is p* C + p* OS = 2a/3b and the quantities demanded of computers and OS are q* C + q* OS = a - b×2a/3b = a/3.
17
Complementarity What if the firms merge? Then the new firm bundles a computer and an operating system and sells the bundle at a price p B. The firm’s problem is to choose p B to maximize p B D(p B ) – F B = p B (a – bp B ) – F B.
18
Complementarity What if the firms merge? Then the new firm bundles a computer and an operating system and sells the bundle at a price p B. The firm’s problem is to choose p B to maximize p B D(p B ) – F B = p B (a – bp B ) – F B. Solution is p* B = a/2b < 2a/3b.
19
Complementarity When the firms merge (or fully cooperate) the price of a computer and an OS is p* B = a/2b a/3.
20
Complementarity When the firms merge (or fully cooperate) the price of a computer and an OS is p* B = a/2b a/3. The merged firm supplies more computers and OS at a lower price than do the competing firms. Why?
21
Complementarity The noncooperative firms ignore the external benefit (complementarity) each creates for the other. So each undersupplies the market, causing a higher market price. These externalities are fully internalized in the merged firm, inducing it to supply more computers and OS and thereby cause a lower market price.
22
Complementarity More typical cooperation consists of contracts between component manufacturers and an assembler of a final product. Examples are: Car components and a car assembler. A computer assembler and manufacturers of CPUs, hard drives, memory chips, etc.
23
Complementarity Alternatives include: Revenue-sharing. Two firms share the revenue from the final product made up from the two firms’ components. Licensing. Let firms making complements to your product use your technology for a low fee so they make large quantities of complements, thereby increasing the value of your product to consumers.
24
Information Technologies; Lock-In Strong complementarities or network externalities make switching from one technology to another very costly. This is called lock-in. E.g., In the USA, it is costly to switch from speaking English to speaking French. How do markets operate when there are switching costs or network externalities?
25
Competition & Switching Costs Producer’s cost per month of providing a network service is c per customer. Customer’s switching cost is s. Producer offers a one month discount, d. Rate of interest is r.
26
Competition & Switching Costs All producers set the same nondiscounted price of p per month. When is switching producers rational for a customer?
27
Competition & Switching Costs Consumer’s cost of not switching is
28
Competition & Switching Costs Consumer’s cost of not switching is Consumer’s cost from switching is
29
Competition & Switching Costs Consumer’s cost of not switching is Consumer’s cost from switching is Consumer should switch if
30
Competition & Switching Costs Consumer’s cost of not switching is Consumer’s cost from switching is Consumer should switch if i.e. if
31
Competition & Switching Costs Consumer should switch if Producer competition will ensure at a market equilibrium that customers are indifferent between switching or not I.e., the equilibrium value of the discount only just makes it worthwhile for the customer to switch.
32
Competition & Switching Costs With d = s, the present-value of the producer’s profits is
33
Competition & Switching Costs At equilibrium the present-value of the producer’s profit is zero. The producer’s price is its marginal cost plus a markup that is a fraction of the consumer’s switching cost.
34
Competition & Switching Costs At equilibrium the present-value of the producer’s profit is zero. The producer’s price is its marginal cost plus a markup that is a fraction of the consumer’s switching cost. If advertising reduces the marginal cost of servicing a consumer by a then
35
Competition & Switching Costs At equilibrium the present-value of the producer’s profit is zero. The producer’s price is its marginal cost plus a markup that is a fraction of the consumer’s switching cost. If advertising reduces the marginal cost of servicing a consumer by a then
36
Competition & Network Externalities Individuals 1,…,1000. Each can buy one unit of a good, providing a network externality. Person v values a unit of the good at nv, where n is the number of persons who buy the good.
37
Competition & Network Externalities Individuals 1,…,1000. Each can buy one unit of a good providing a network externality. Person v values a unit of the good at nv, where n is the number of persons who buy the good. At a price p, what is the quantity demanded of the good?
38
Competition & Network Externalities If v is the marginal buyer, valuing the good at nv = p, then all buyers v’ > v value the good more, and so buy it. Quantity demanded is n = 1000 - v. So inverse demand is p = n(1000-n).
39
Competition & Network Externalities 01000 n Willingness-to-pay p = n(1000-n) Demand Curve
40
Competition & Network Externalities Suppose all suppliers have the same marginal production cost, c.
41
Competition & Network Externalities 01000 n Demand Curve Supply Curve c Willingness-to-pay p = n(1000-n)
42
Competition & Network Externalities What are the market equilibria?
43
Competition & Network Externalities What are the market equilibria? (a) No buyer buys, no seller supplies. If n = 0, then value nv = 0 for all buyers v, so no buyer buys. If no buyer buys, then no seller supplies.
44
Competition & Network Externalities 01000 n Demand Curve Supply Curve c Willingness-to-pay p = n(1000-n) (a)
45
Competition & Network Externalities 01000 n Demand Curve Supply Curve n’ c Willingness-to-pay p = n(1000-n) (a)
46
Competition & Network Externalities What are the market equilibria? (b) A small number, n’, of buyers buy. small n’ small network externality value n’v good is bought only by buyers with n’v c; i.e., only large v v’ = c/n’.
47
Competition & Network Externalities 01000 n Demand Curve Supply Curve n’ (b) n” (c) (a) c Willingness-to-pay p = n(1000-n)
48
Competition & Network Externalities What are the market equilibria? (c) A large number, n”, of buyers buy. Large n” large network externality value n”v good is bought only by buyers with n’v c; i.e., up to small v v” = c/n”.
49
Competition & Network Externalities 01000 n Demand Curve Supply Curve n’ (b) n” (c) c Which equilibrium is likely to occur? Willingness-to-pay p = n(1000-n) (a)
50
Competition & Network Externalities Suppose the market expands whenever willingness- to-pay exceeds marginal production cost, c.
51
Competition & Network Externalities 01000 n Demand Curve Supply Curve n’n” c Which equilibrium is likely to occur? Willingness-to-pay p = n(1000-n)
52
Competition & Network Externalities 01000 n Demand Curve Supply Curve n’n” c Which equilibrium is likely to occur? Willingness-to-pay p = n(1000-n) Unstable
53
Competition & Network Externalities 01000 n Demand Curve Supply Curve n” c Which equilibrium is likely to occur? Willingness-to-pay p = n(1000-n) Stable
54
Information Essentially, anything that can be digitized is information. Information Goods: books, database, magazines, movies, music, web pages.
55
Cost of producing information Information is costly to produce but cheap to reproduce. In economics terms, production of an information good involves high fixed cost but low marginal cost. Therefore, we price information according to its value, not its cost.
56
Managing Intellectual Property Since an information good can be reproduced cheaply, others can copy it cheaply. Intellectual property is very important, but enforcement is an issue. e.g., patent, copyright, trademark When managing IP, the goal should be to choose the terms and conditions that maximize the value of the IP, not the ones that maximize the protection.
57
Information as an “Experience Good” A good is an experience good if consumers must experience it to value it. Information is an experience good every time it’s consumed. How do you know today’s Wall Street Journal is worth $1? Most media producers overcome the experience the experience good problem through branding and reputation.
58
Information as an “Experience Good” (Cont’d) The brand name of the wall Street Journal is one of its chief asset, and the Journal heavily in building a reputation for accuracy, timeliness, and relevance. The Journal’s online edition carries over the look and feel of the print version extending the same authority, brand identity, and customer loyalty from the print product to the on-line product.
59
Rights Management Should a good be sold outright, licensed for production by others, or rented? How is the ownership right of the good to be managed?
60
Rights Management Suppose production costs are negligible. Market demand is p(y). The firm wishes to
61
Rights Management
64
The rights owner now allows a free trial period. This causes a consumption increase;
65
Rights Management The rights owner now allows a free trial period. This causes a consumption increase; lower sales per consumption unit
66
Rights Management The rights owner now allows a free trial period. This causes a consumption increase; lower sales per consumption unit increase in value to all users increase in willingness-to- pay;
67
Rights Management
68
The firm’s problem is now to
69
Rights Management The firm’s problem is now to This problem must have the same solution as
70
Rights Management The firm’s problem is now to This problem must have the same solution as So
71
Rights Management
72
higher profit
73
Rights Management lower profit
74
Sharing Intellectual Property Produce a lot for direct sales, or only a little for multiple rentals? Sell a tool, or rent it? Allow a movie to be shown only at a theatre, or sell only to video rental stores, or sell only by pay-per-view, or sell DVDs in retail stores? When is selling for rental more profitable than selling for personal use only?
75
Sharing Intellectual Property F is the fixed cost of designing the good. c is the constant marginal cost of copying the good. p(y) is the market demand. Direct sales problem is to
76
Sharing Intellectual Property F is the fixed cost of designing the good. c is the constant marginal cost of copying the good. p(y) is the market demand. Direct sales problem is to
77
Sharing Intellectual Property Is selling for rental more profitable? Each rental unit is used by k > 1 consumers. So y units sold x = ky consumption units.
78
Sharing Intellectual Property Is selling for rental more profitable? Each rental unit is used by k > 1 consumers. So y units sold x = ky consumption units. Marginal consumer’s willingness-to-pay is p(x) = p(ky).
79
Sharing Intellectual Property Is selling for rental more profitable? Each rental unit used by k > 1 consumers. So y units sold x = ky consumption units. Marginal consumer’s willingness-to-pay is p(x) = p(ky). Rental transaction cost t reduces willingness-to-pay to p(ky) - t.
80
Sharing Intellectual Property Rental transaction cost t reduces willingness-to-pay to p(ky) - t. Rental store’s willingness-to-pay is
81
Sharing Intellectual Property Rental transaction cost t reduces willingness-to-pay to p(ky) - t. Rental store’s willingness-to-pay is Producer’s sale-for-rental problem is
82
Sharing Intellectual Property Rental transaction cost t reduces willingness-to-pay to p(ky) - t. Rental store’s willingness-to-pay is Producer’s sale-for-rental problem is
83
Sharing Intellectual Property Rental transaction cost t reduces willingness-to-pay to p(ky) - t. Rental store’s willingness-to-pay is Producer’s sale-for-rental problem is
84
Sharing Intellectual Property This is the same as the direct sale problem except for the marginal cost.
85
Sharing Intellectual Property This is the same as the direct sale problem except for the marginal cost. Direct sale is better for the producer if
86
Sharing Intellectual Property Direct sale is better for the producer if i.e. if
87
Sharing Intellectual Property Direct sale is better for the producer if Direct sale is better if replication cost c is low rental transaction cost t is high rentals per item, k, is small.
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.