Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published byEzra Lang Modified over 9 years ago
1
Existence of Natural Monopoly in Multiproduct Firms Competition Policy and Market Regulation MEFI- Università di Pavia
2
Multiproduct Sub-additivity Two products q 1, q 2 Cost function. C(q 1, q 2 ) Def.: q i a vector of the 2 products: q i = (q 1 i, q 2 i ) N vectors such that:∑ i q 1 i =q 1 and ∑ i q 2 i =q 2 Sub-additive cost function: C(∑ i q 1 i, ∑ i q 2 i ) = C (∑ i q i ) < ∑ i C (q i )
3
What drives multiproduct sub- additivity? Economies of scope: C(q 1, q 2 )< C(q 1,0)+ C(0, q 2 ) Multiproduct economies of scale 1.Declining Average Cost for a specific product 2.Declining ray average cost (varying quantities of a set of multiple products, bundled in fixed proportions)
4
Declining Average Incremental Cost Incremental cost of production for q 1 (holding q 2 constant): IC(q 1 I q 2 ) = C(q 1, q 2 ) - C(0, q 2 ) Average incremental cost: AIC =[C(q 1, q 2 ) - C(0, q 2 )] /q 1 If AIC ↓ when q 1 ↑ : declining average incremental cost of q 1 A measure of single product economies of scale in a multiproduct context We can see if the cost function has declining average IC for each product
5
Declining Ray Average Costs Fix the proportion of multiple products: (q 1 /q 2 = k) What happens to costs if we increase both products output holding K constant? Does the average cost of the bundle decrease as the size of the bundle increases?
6
Declining Ray Average Costs We can consider different proportions k, and see if we have economies of scale along each ray k in the q 1, q 2 space We have multiproduct economies of scale for each combination of q 1 /q 2 if: C(λ q 1, λq 2 ) < λC(q 1,q 2 )
7
Declining Ray Average Costs: Examples Consider C(q 1,q 2 ) = q 1 + q 2 + (q 1 q 2 ) 1/3 It is characterized by multiproduct economies of scale as: λC(q 1,q 2 )= λq 1 + λq 2 + λ (q 1 q 2 ) 1/3 C(λq 1, λq 2 ) = λq 1 + λq 2 + λ 1/3 (q 1 q 2 ) 1/3 and C(λq 1, λq 2 ) < λC(q 1,q 2 )
8
No Multiproduct sub-additivity HOWEVER this cost function exhibits diseconomies of scope as: C(q 1,0) = q 1 C(0, q 2 ) = q 2 C(q 1,0)+ C(0, q 2 ) = q 1 + q 2 < q 1 + q 2 + (q 1 q 2 ) 1/3 = C(q 1,q 2 ) THEREFORE this cost function is not sub-additive, despite multiproduct economies of scale, as economies of scope are lacking It is more convenient to produce the two products in two separate firms No Natural Monopoly
9
An example with multiproduct sub- additivity Sub-additivity in a multiproduct context requires both cost complementarity (economies of scope) and multiproduct economies of scale, over at least some range of output. Consider the following cost function: C(q 1,q 2 ) = q 1 1/4 + q 2 1/4 -(q 1 q 2 ) 1/4 1.It exhibits economies of scope (..look at -(q 1 q 2 ) 1/4 ) C(q 1,0)+ C(0, q 2 ) = q 1 1/4 + q 2 1/4 > q 1 1/4 + q 2 1/4 -(q 1 q 2 ) 1/4 = C(q 1,q 2 ) Then: C(q 1,q 2 ) < C(q 1,0)+ C(0, q 2 )
10
An example with multiproduct sub-additivity: C(q 1,q 2 ) = q 1 1/4 + q 2 1/4 -(q 1 q 2 ) 1/4 1.It exhibits multiproduct economies of scale (for any combination K of the two outputs the cost of production of this combination increases less than proportionally with an increase in the scale of the bundle,… by virtue of power ¼ in the cost function) 2.For the same reason it exhibits product specific economies of scale (declining average IC, at any output) 3.It can be shown it is a globally sub-additive cost function (i.e. sub-additive at every level of output)
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.