Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

PREFERENCES AND UTILITY

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "PREFERENCES AND UTILITY"— Presentation transcript:

1 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY
Chapter 3 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

2 Outline Preference Utility Axioms of rational choice
Completeness Transitivity Continuity Utility Marginal rate of substitution (MRS) and convexity Graph Mathematical derivation

3 Axioms of Rational Choice
Completeness if A and B are any two situations, an individual can always specify exactly one of these possibilities: A is preferred to B B is preferred to A A and B are equally attractive

4 Axioms of Rational Choice
Transitivity if A is preferred to B, and B is preferred to C, then A is preferred to C assumes that the individual’s choices are internally consistent

5 Axioms of Rational Choice
Continuity if A is preferred to B, then situations suitably “close to” A must also be preferred to B used to analyze individuals’ responses to relatively small changes in income and prices

6 Utility Given these assumptions, it is possible to show that people are able to rank in order all possible situations from least desirable to most Economists call this ranking utility (introduced by Jeremy Bentham 19 century) if A is preferred to B, then the utility assigned to A exceeds the utility assigned to B U(A) > U(B)

7 Utility Utility rankings are ordinal in nature
they record the relative desirability of commodity bundles Any set of numbers that accurately reflects a person’s preference ordering will do. Because utility measures are not unique, it makes no sense to consider how much more utility is gained from A than from B It is also impossible to compare utilities between people (may use very different scale)

8 Utility Utility is affected by the consumption of physical commodities, psychological attitudes, peer group pressures, personal experiences, and the general cultural environment Economists generally devote attention to quantifiable options while holding constant the other things that affect utility ceteris paribus assumption

9 utility = U(x1, x2,…, xn; other things)
Assume that an individual must choose among consumption goods x1, x2,…, xn The individual’s rankings can be shown by a utility function of the form: utility = U(x1, x2,…, xn; other things) x’s refer to the quantities of the goods that might be chosen this function is unique up to an order-preserving transformation

10 utility Quite often to write as utility = U(x1, x2,…, xn)
If only two goods utility = U(x, y) Everything else is being held constant

11 Arguments of utility functions
The utility functionis used to represent how an individual ranks certain bundles of goods that might be purchased at one point in time. On occasion we will use other arguments in the utility function utility = U(w): wealth utility = U(c,h): consumption and nonwork time utility = U(c1, c2): consumption in period 1 and 2

12 Economic Goods In the utility function, the x’s are assumed to be “goods” more is preferred to less Quantity of y Preferred to x*, y* ? y* Worse than x*, y* Quantity of x x*

13 Trade and substitution
Most economic activity involves trading between individuals. When someone buys a loaf of bread, he or she is voluntarily giving up one thing (money)

14 Indifference Curves An indifference curve shows a set of consumption bundles among which the individual is indifferent Quantity of y Combinations (x1, y1) and (x2, y2) provide the same level of utility y1 y2 U1 Quantity of x x1 x2

15 Indifference curve The slope of the indifference curve is negative, showing that if the individual is forced to give up some y, he or she must be compensated by an additional amount of x

16 Marginal Rate of Substitution
The negative of the slope of the indifference curve at any point is called the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) Quantity of y y1 y2 U1 Quantity of x x1 x2

17 Marginal Rate of Substitution
MRS changes as x and y change reflects the individual’s willingness to trade y for x Quantity of y At (x1, y1), the indifference curve is steeper. The person would be willing to give up more y to gain additional units of x At (x2, y2), the indifference curve is flatter. The person would be willing to give up less y to gain additional units of x y1 y2 U1 Quantity of x x1 x2

18 MRS The slope of U1 and the MRS tell us something about the trade this person will voluntarily make. MRS diminishes between x1,y1 and x2,y2

19 Indifference Curve Map
Each point must have an indifference curve through it Quantity of y U1 U2 U3 Increasing utility U1 < U2 < U3 Quantity of x

20 Indifference curve map
Indifference curves are similar to contour lines on a map in that they represent lines of equal “altitude”

21 Transitivity Can any two of an individual’s indifference curves intersect? The individual is indifferent between A and C. The individual is indifferent between B and C. Transitivity suggests that the individual should be indifferent between A and B Quantity of y But B is preferred to A because B contains more x and y than A C B U2 A U1 Quantity of x

22 Convexity of indifference curve
An alternative way of stating the principle of a diminishing marginal rate of substitution (MRS) uses the mathematical notion of a convex set

23 Convexity A set of points is convex if any two points can be joined by a straight line that is contained completely within the set Quantity of y The assumption of a diminishing MRS is equivalent to the assumption that all combinations of x and y which are preferred to or x* and y* form a convex set y* U1 Quantity of x x*

24 Convexity If the indifference curve is convex, then the combination (x1 + x2)/2, (y1 + y2)/2 will be preferred to either (x1,y1) or (x2,y2) Quantity of y This implies that “well-balanced” bundles are preferred to bundles that are heavily weighted toward one commodity y1 (y1 + y2)/2 y2 U1 Quantity of x x1 (x1 + x2)/2 x2

25 Convexity and balance in consumption
Individual prefer some balance in their consumption Any proportional combination of two indifferent bundles of goods will be preferred to the initial The assumption of convexity and diminishing MRS rule out the possibility of an indifference curve being straight over any portion of its length

26 Utility and the MRS Suppose an individual’s preferences for hamburgers (y) and soft drinks (x) can be represented by Solving for y, we get y = 100/x Solving for MRS = -dy/dx: MRS = -dy/dx = 100/x2

27 Utility and the MRS Note that as x rises, MRS falls
MRS = -dy/dx = 100/x2 Note that as x rises, MRS falls when x = 5, MRS = 4 (the person is willing to give up 4 hamburger for another soft drink) when x = 20, MRS = 0.25 Point C is midway between points A and B and has 12.5 hamburgers and 12.5 soft drinks. Utility =12.5

28 A mathematical derivation
A mathematical derivation of the MRS concept provided additional insights about the shape of indifference curves and the nature of preferences

29 Marginal Utility Suppose that an individual has a utility function of the form utility = U(x,y) The total differential of U is Along any indifference curve, utility is constant (dU = 0)

30 Deriving the MRS Therefore, we get:
MRS is the ratio of the marginal utility of x to the marginal utility of y

31 Diminishing Marginal Utility and the MRS
Intuitively, it seems that the assumption of decreasing marginal utility is related to the concept of a diminishing MRS diminishing MRS requires that the utility function be quasi-concave this is independent of how utility is measured diminishing marginal utility depends on how utility is measured Thus, these two concepts are different

32 Convexity of Indifference Curves
Suppose that the utility function is We can simplify the algebra by taking the logarithm of this function U*(x,y) = ln[U(x,y)] = 0.5 ln x ln y

33 Convexity of Indifference Curves
Thus, MRS is diminishing as x increases and y decreases. The indifference curves are convex

34 Convexity of Indifference Curves
If the utility function is U(x,y) = x + xy + y There is no advantage to transforming this utility function, so

35 Convexity of Indifference Curves
Suppose that the utility function is For this example, it is easier to use the transformation (order preserving) U*(x,y) = [U(x,y)]2 = x2 + y2

36 Convexity of Indifference Curves
Thus, as x increases and y increases, the MRS increases. The curve are concave, not convex, and clearly not a quasi-concave function

37 Utility functions for specific preferences
Individuals’ rankings of commodity bundles and the utility functions implied by this rankings are unobservable. All we can learn about people’s preferences must come from the behavior we observe when they respond to changes in income, prices, and other factors Examine a few of the forms of utility functions is useful , both because such an examination may offer some insights into observed behavior and understand the properties of such functions can be of some help in solving problems.

38 Examples of Utility Functions
Cobb-Douglas Utility utility = U(x,y) = xy where  and  are positive constants The relative sizes of  and  indicate the relative importance of the goods Since utility is unique only up to a monotonic transformation, it is often convenient to normalize these parameters so that α+β=1

39 Examples of Utility Functions
Perfect Substitutes utility = U(x,y) = x + y Quantity of y The indifference curves will be linear. The MRS will be constant along the indifference curve. U1 U2 U3 Quantity of x

40 Perfect substitutions
utility = U(x,y) = x + y

41 Perfect substitutes MRS is constant along the entire indifference curve. A person would be willing to give up the same amount of y to get one more x no matter how much x was being consumed. A diminishing MRS do not apply Might describe the relationship between different brands of the same product (e.g. willing to give up 10 gallons of Shell in exchange for 10 gallons of Exxon

42 Examples of Utility Functions
Perfect Complements utility = U(x,y) = min (x, y) Quantity of y The indifference curves will be L-shaped. Only by choosing more of the two goods together can utility be increased. U1 U2 U3 Quantity of x

43 utility = U(x,y) = min (x, y)
Perfect complements utility = U(x,y) = min (x, y) Neither of the two goods will be in excess only if x = y, that is y/x= /  MRS=infinite for y/x> /  =undefined for y/x= /  = for y/x< / 

44 Perfect complements These preferences would apply to goods that “ go together”– Coffee and cream, Peanut butter and jelly, and cream cheese and lox

45 Examples of Utility Functions
CES Utility (Constant elasticity of substitution) utility = U(x,y) = x/ + y/ when   0 and  ≦ 1. utility = U(x,y) = ln x + ln y when  = 0 Perfect substitutes   = 1 Cobb-Douglas   = 0 Perfect complements   = - (less obvious-- using a limits argument)

46 Examples of Utility Functions
CES Utility (Constant elasticity of substitution) The elasticity of substitution () is equal to 1/(1 - ) Perfect substitutes   =  Fixed proportions   = 0

47 Homothetic Preferences
If the MRS depends only on the ratio of the amounts of the two goods, not on the quantities of the goods, the utility function is homothetic Perfect substitutes  MRS is the same at every point Perfect complements  MRS =  if y/x > /, undefined if y/x = /, and MRS = 0 if y/x < /

48 Homothetic Preferences
For the general Cobb-Douglas function, the MRS can be found as

49 Homothetic preference
The importance of homothetic functions is that one indifference curve is much like another. Slopes of the curves depend only on the ratio y/x, not on how far the curve is from the origin. We can only look at one indifference curve or at a few nearby curves without fearing that our results would change dramatically at very different levels of utility.

50 Nonhomothetic Preferences
Some utility functions do not exhibit homothetic preferences utility = U(x,y) = x + ln y MRS diminishes as y decreases, but it is independent of the quantity of x consumed.

51 Nonhomothetic preference
Contrary to the homothetic case, a doubling of both x and y doubles the MRS in this case rather than leaving it unchanged.

52 The Many-Good Case Suppose utility is a function of n goods given by
utility = U(x1, x2,…, xn) The total differential of U is

53 The Many-Good Case We can find the MRS between any two goods by setting dU = 0 Rearranging, we get

54 Multigood Indifference Surfaces
We will define an indifference surface as being the set of points in n dimensions that satisfy the equation U(x1,x2,…xn) = k where k is any preassigned constant

55 Multigood Indifference Surfaces
If the utility function is quasi-concave, the set of points for which U  k will be convex all of the points on a line joining any two points on the U = k indifference surface will also have U  k

56 Important Points to Note:
If individuals obey certain behavioral postulates, they will be able to rank all commodity bundles the ranking can be represented by a utility function in making choices, individuals will act as if they were maximizing this function Utility functions for two goods can be illustrated by an indifference curve map

57 Important Points to Note:
The negative of the slope of the indifference curve measures the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) the rate at which an individual would trade an amount of one good (y) for one more unit of another good (x) MRS decreases as x is substituted for y individuals prefer some balance in their consumption choices

58 Important Points to Note:
A few simple functional forms can capture important differences in individuals’ preferences for two (or more) goods Cobb-Douglas function linear function (perfect substitutes) fixed proportions function (perfect complements) CES function includes the other three as special cases

59 Important Points to Note:
It is a simple matter to generalize from two-good examples to many goods studying peoples’ choices among many goods can yield many insights the mathematics of many goods is not especially intuitive, so we will rely on two-good cases to build intuition

60 The end


Download ppt "PREFERENCES AND UTILITY"

Similar presentations


Ads by Google