Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published bySuzanna Stanley Modified over 9 years ago
1
Lecture Notes
2
Monopoly Market environment where there is only one firm in the market Firm faces ALL of demand So monopoly profit = p(y)y – c(y) Where p(y) = inverse market demand let p(y)y = r(y) revenue function Monopolistic problem: Choose y to Max r(y) – c(y) First order conditions are given by: MR = MC
3
The same condition we got with perfect competition But now MR does not equal P (i.e. firms not price takers) Two effects of changing y (say increase y) on revenues 1-sell more so revenue increases 2-price decreases so revenue decreases ∆ r (y) = p ∆y + y ∆p ∆ r(y)/ ∆ y = MR = p + y ∆p/ ∆y or: For price takers ∆p=0 => ∆r = p ∆y But now P decreases as y increases so the second term matters.
4
Now both 1 and 2 measure Marginal Revenue (MR) MR= ∆r/ ∆y = p + y ∆p/ ∆y = p(1 + (y/p)(∆p/ ∆y) = p(y) (1 + 1/ε) Since ε = price elasticity of demand = (p/y)(∆y/∆p) => can re-write optimal condition, MR = MC as: p(y) (1 + 1/ ε(y)) = mc (y) Or p(y) (1- 1/| ε(y)|) = mc (y) Since ε < 0 Also recall that | ε | > 0 elastic | ε | < 1 inelastic So that if demand elastic regions | ε | > 1 MR > 0 but if demand inelastic MR < 0
5
The above implies that the Monopolist only operates in elastic portion of Demand since MR < 0 when demand inelastic and profit max. requires MR = MC but MC < 0 is unlikely (impossible). Now with linear demand… P(y) = a –b y So R (y) = ay –by 2 => MR= a – 2by Notice 3 things: 1. MR = D at y=0 2. slope of MR = 2 times the slope of demand (i.e., twice as steep). 3. MR = 0 where | ε | = 1 (this is always true not just for linear Demand)
6
Look at tax example: suppose c(y) = cy => mc = c P(y) = a-by so MR = a -2by MC AC MR Ymy Pm D
7
Now suppose a tax on the monopolist = t (quantity tax) so pc = ps + t So mc w/ tax is c + t or c(y) = (c+ t)y => before profit max where c = a -2by Or y* = a-c/2b Now MC = c + t = a – 2by = MR So y* = (a-c-t)/2b => Δy/ Δ t = -1/(2b) (why?) What is the impact of the tax on price, p? Recall slope of demand function = Δp/ Δy = -b, so The tax is imposed => y changes by -1/(2b) then The price changes by – b, the overall impact is both of these together, Or – b times -1/(2b) = -1/2 Interpretation: if t increases by $1 => price increases by $.50
8
But note that p may actually increase more than by the amount of tax. See book for example Yt y* C + t MC = C pt P* MR D
9
Now look at efficiency and compare to perfect competition Again assume MC = C (constant returns) in the long run Produce at (p m, y m ) Ym yc MC=LRAC Pm Pc=c MR D Deadweight loss to society But competitive firms would produce at MC = D Or (p c, y c ) which is the point that maximizes net surplus to society.
10
Or if upward sloping LRMC Ym yc Pm Pc MR D Deadweight loss to society MC
11
=> appears that monopolist is inefficient (i.e. does not max society’s net surplus) Public policy: may be to get rid of monopolies (1) contestable markets i.e. free entry => if profit > 0 more firms enter so profit = o even with one firm. (2) economies of scale and scope Consider natural monopoly (economies of scale) LRMC LRAC Pm Pt Ym MR D
12
Only one firm can cheaply produce given demand but (1) if p=mc=Pso(socially optimum price) Firms makes a loss and leaves (2) if p=pm => deadweight loss (3) if p=AC=p f (fair price) still a loss in profit but firm can operate But if break up of monopoly: Pc > Pm > Pf >Pso => competition is not more efficient due to economies of scale. Same may to be true due to economies of scope.
13
Price Discrimination 3 different types A. Perfect price discrimination—price the monopolists sells is just equal to your willingness to pay => With no price discrimination produce at (pm, ym) but this assumes no ability to discriminate Now perfectly discriminate => D=MR and produce at Yc which is efficient (assuming $1 to producer is the same as $1 to consumer since CS=0) Pm Pe Ym Ye D MC MR
14
2 nd degree Price Discrimination P i = f(y i ) i.e. how much you pay depends on your consumption Examples: utilities, bulk discounts for large purchases 3 rd degree price discrimination-different groups get different prices but individuals within a group get the same price Most common type: Examples 1. movie theatre discounts (kids v. adults) 2. local ski discounts (locals v. non-locals) More formally suppose 2 groups with different demand => max P1 (Y1) Y1 + P2 (Y2) Y2 – C(Y1 + Y2) by: MR 1 – MC(Y1 + Y2) = 0 MR 2 – MC(Y1 + Y2) = 0
15
Combine to get MR1 = MC(Y1 + Y2) = MR2 or P1 [1- 1/| ε 1 |] = MC (Y1 +Y2) = P2 [1-1/| ε 2 |] If P1 > P2 =>[1-1/| ε 1 |] < 1 – 1/| ε 2 | or 1/| ε 1 | > 1/| ε 2 | or | ε 2 | > | ε 1 | i.e. for P1 > P2 demand for group 1 must be more inelastic Graphically, assume C= MC C Y1 P1 C Group 1 D1D1 MR 1 Y2 P2 Group 2 D2D2 MR 2
16
Innovation—monopolies have more incentive to innovate (at least this is the argument) Define innovation Just a decrease in MC to MC2 assuming constant returns P Q MC1 MC2
17
What are the incentives to innovate for monopoly? I.e. increase profit due to innovation = shaded area. Why? P Y MC1 MC2 D MR
18
What are incentives to innovate for perfectly competitive industry? None unless (1) innovative technology is secret or (2) a patent system exists Under a patent system what is the incentive? What are increased profits to patent holder? 1 st what does patent holders MR curve look like? As long y < y* MR = C ; i.e. he’s a price taker. P Q MC1 MC2 Y* D C C1
19
But if y > y* the firm becomes sole supplier R= p(y)y so MR is downward sloping and determined by D when y > y*. Note: as long as C > C* ; y = y* in the market. This is a small innovation. But if C y* then this is a large innovation. MR P Y C C1 C* Y* D
20
Now just look at a small innovation (i.e. y = y* before and after innovation) MR P Y C C2 D Notice that the incentive to innovate for a competitive industry is greater than for a monopoly because output is larger for the competitive firm. Incentive to innovate to competitive industry
21
Q: What if economies of scale in innovation (i.e. small firms in competitive industry don’t have resources to innovate) A: Firms specialize in innovating, gain patents and license to small competitive firms Example: agriculture where innovating is done by Universities Seed companies Etc.
22
Monopolistic Competition Characteristics Large numbe r of potential sellers All small relative to market Differentiated product Easy entry and exit The short-run looks like a monoply Ym Pm MR D MC ATC Profit
23
Profit can also be negative or zero in the short-run. If negative => firms exit if p< avc. Long-run equilibrium is just like for competition: If profit > 0 => entry which drives profit down. If profit exit which drives profit up. Therefore, long-run equilibrium is where profit equals zero, where no exit or entry. Po Pc Qo Qc MR D MC ATC
24
Notice that at Equilibrium but P > MC Resource Allocation & Efficiency Since MSC does not equal MSB or MSB > MSC => inefficient p.c. firm would produce the efficient amount. Might be efficient if benefit from different products > Cost of producing different products => in long run (1) each firm is on its demand curve (2) each firm chooses y to max profit (3) entry forces profit = 0 (4) P > MC => inefficient
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.