Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published byOlivia Nash Modified over 9 years ago
1
ECONOMIC GROWTH Lviv, September 2012
2
Growth in Finland
7
The Sources of Economic Growth Production function Y = AF(K, N) Decompose into growth rate form: the growth accounting equation Y/Y = A/A + a K K/K + a N N/N The a terms are the elasticities of output with respect to the inputs (capital and labor)
8
The Sources of Economic Growth Interpretation A rise of 10% in A raises output by 10% A rise of 10% in K raises output by a K times 10% A rise of 10% in N raises output by a N times 10% Both a K and a N are less than 1 due to diminishing marginal productivity
9
The Sources of Economic Growth Growth accounting Four steps in breaking output growth into its causes (productivity growth, capital input growth, labor input growth) 1.Get data on Y/Y, K/K, and N/N, adjusting for quality changes 2.Estimate a K and a N from historical data 3.Calculate the contributions of K and N as a K K/K and a N N/N, respectively 4.Calculate productivity growth as the residual: A/A Y/Y – a K K/K – a N N/N
10
The Sources of Economic Growth Growth accounting and the productivity slowdown Denison’s results for 1929–1982 Entire period output growth 2.92%; due to labor 1.34%; due to capital 0.56%; due to productivity 1.02% Pre-1948 capital growth was much slower than post-1948 Post-1973 labor growth slightly slower than pre-1973
11
Sources of Economic Growth in the United States (Denison) (Percent per Year)
12
Productivity Levels, 1947-2005
13
Productivity Labor TFP Growth rate Productivity of K/N Labor productivity growth may exceed TFP growth because of faster growth of capital relative to growth of labor
15
Technological Progress in the Solow Model A new variable: E = labor efficiency Assume: Technological progress is labor-augmenting: it increases labor efficiency at the exogenous rate g = ∆E/E: We now write the production function as: Y = F(K,L*E) where L*E is the number of effective workers. Increases in efficiency will have the same effect on output as increases in the labor force.
16
The Solow Model Basic assumptions and variables Population and work force grow at same rate n Economy is closed and for now there is no govt. (G 0) C t Y t – I t Rewrite everything in per-worker terms: (k t is also called the capital-labor ratio) Therefore, saving and investment per effective worker is: sy=sf(k)
17
The Solow Model The per-worker production function y t f(k t ) Assume no productivity growth for now (we will add it later) Plot of per-worker production function Same shape as aggregate production function
18
The per-worker production function
19
The Solow Model Steady states Steady state: y t, c t, and k t are constant over time Gross investment must Replace worn out capital, δK t Expand so the capital stock grows as the economy grows, nK t Provide capital for the new “effective” workers created by technological progress, I t (δ+n g)K t If so, then ( + n + g)k = break-even investment: the amount of investment necessary to keep k constant.
20
The Solow Model C t Y t – I t Y t – (δ+n g)K t In per-worker terms, in steady state c f(k) (δ+n g)k t Plot of c, f(k), and (δ+n g)k t
21
The relationship of consumption per worker to the capital–labor ratio in the steady state
22
The Solow Model Increasing k will increase c up to a point This is k G in the figure, the Golden Rule capital-labor ratio For k beyond this point, c will decline But we assume henceforth that k is less than k G, so c always rises as k rises
23
The Solow Model Reaching the steady state Suppose saving is proportional to current income: S t sY t, where s is the saving rate, which is between 0 and 1 Equating saving to investment gives sY t (n d + g)K t
24
The Solow Model Putting this in per-worker terms gives sf(k) (n δ + g)k Plot of sf(k) and (n δ + g)k
25
Determining the capital–labor ratio in the steady state
26
The steady state The only possible steady-state capital-labor ratio is k* Output at that point is y* = f(k*); consumption is c* = f(k*) – (n + d + g)k* If k begins at some level other than k*, it will move toward k* For k below k*, saving > the amount of investment needed to keep k constant, so k rises For k above k*, saving < the amount of investment needed to keep k constant, so k falls
27
Long-run growth To summarize: With no productivity growth, the economy reaches a steady state, with constant capital-labor ratio, output per worker, and consumption per worker. Therefore, the fundamental determinants of long-run living standards are: 1.The saving rate 2.Population growth 3.Productivity growth
28
The fundamental determinants of long-run living standards: the saving rate Higher saving rate means higher capital-labor ratio, higher output per worker, and higher consumption per worker
29
The fundamental determinants of long-run living standards: population growth Higher population growth means a lower capital-labor ratio, lower output per worker, and lower consumption per worker
30
Fundamental Determinants of Long-run Living Standards: Productivity Growth In equilibrium, productivity improvement increases the capital-labor ratio, output per worker, and consumption per worker: Productivity improvement directly improves the amount that can be produced at any capital-labor ratio and the increase in output per worker increases the supply of saving, causing the long-run capital-labor ratio to rise
31
Repetito
32
Growth Empirics: Balanced growth Solow model’s steady state exhibits balanced growth - many variables grow at the same rate. Solow model predicts Y/L and K/L grow at the same rate (g), so K/Y should be constant. This is true in the real world. Solow model predicts real wage grows at same rate as Y/L, while real rental price is constant. Also true in the real world.
33
Growth Empirics: Convergence Solow model predicts that, other things equal, “poor” countries (with lower Y/L and K/L) should grow faster than “rich” ones. If true, then the income gap between rich & poor countries would shrink over time, causing living standards to “converge.” This does not always occur because “other things” aren’t equal. In samples of countries with similar savings & pop. growth rates, income gaps shrink about 2% per year. In larger samples, after controlling for differences in saving, pop. growth, and human capital, incomes converge about 2% per year.
34
Factor Accumulation vs. Production Efficiency Differences in income per capita among countries can be due to differences in: 1. capital – physical or human – per worker 2. the efficiency of production (the height of the production function) Empirical studies find that: Both factors are important. The two factors are correlated: countries with higher physical or human capital per worker also tend to have higher production efficiency.
35
Endogenous Growth Theory Endogenous growth theory—explaining the sources of productivity growth Aggregate production function Y = AK Constant Marginlal Product of Kapital Human capital Knowledge, skills, and training of individuals Human capital tends to increase in the same proportion as physical capital Research and development programs Increases in capital and output generate increased technical knowledge, which offsets decline in MPK from having more capital
36
Endogenous Growth Theory Implications of endogenous growth Suppose saving is a constant fraction of output: S = sAK Since investment = net investment + depreciation, I = K + dK Setting investment equal to saving implies: K + dK = sAK Rearrange: K/K = sA – d Since output is proportional to capital, Y/Y = K/K, so Y/Y = sA – d Thus the saving rate affects the long-run growth rate (not true in Solow model)
37
Endogenous (New) Growth Theory Summary Endogenous growth theory attempts to explain, rather than assume, the economy’s growth rate The growth rate depends on many things, such as the saving rate, prerequisites for innovative activity, working of the financing industry, regulations (patent laws) Most of those, can be affected by government policies
38
2007
40
Actual vs forecast output
42
Growth may accelerate also because substitution between labor and capital increases (the efficiency in production increases!)
44
Economic Growth in China, the U.S., and Japan
45
The mathematics of the growth problem: Y=Y(K,L) The net investment is: K’ = I – δK = Y – C – δK Let the objective function to be: max ∫ U(C)e – βt dt Here we first move to labor intensive forms so that y = Y/L and k = K/L, and c = C/L. Thus, the net investment equation can be written in the form: K´= knL + Lk’, where n is the growth rate of labor force. Hence k´= y – c – (n+δ)k = φ(k) – c – (n+δ)k
46
Now the current value Hamiltonian can be expressed as: Ĥ = U(c) + μ(φ(k) – c – (n+δ)k) Here u is the control and k the state. Now the necessary conditions are: ∂H/∂c = U´(c) – μ = 0 μ´ = – ∂Ĥ/∂k + βμ = – μ(φ’(k) – (n+δ + β)) and k´= φ(k) – c – (n+δ)k and k(0) = k 0 and lim(T→∞)λ(T) ≥ 0, lim(T→∞) k(T) ≥ 0 and lim(T→∞) λ(T)k(T) = 0
47
Now, using the first– order condition μ = U(c) we get by differentiating both sides μ´ = U”(c)c’ so we can rewrite c’ = (U’/U”)( φ’(k) – (n+δ) – β) U”/U’ is the so– called elasticity of marginal utility, to be denoted by η(c). Its inverse, η(c) – 1, in turn is called the instantaneous elasticity of substitution. Thus, c’/c = – (1/η(c))(φ’(k) – (n+δ) – r) which says that consumption growth is proportional to the difference between the net marginal produce of capital accounting for population growth and depreciation, and the rate of time preference.
48
k´= φ(k) – c – (n+δ)k is the so– called Keynes– Ramsey rule. In the steady state, k’ = 0, optimum consumption is given by: c* = φ’(k*) – (n+δ)k* If we maximize c* with respect to k* we get the optimum consumption as: φ’(k*) = (n+δ) which is the golden rule. Now, we have the steady state, the difference equations give us the dynamic paths, then we have the draw the phase diagram and analyze the dynamics of k and c. As usual, in this kind of models, the solution has the saddle point property. Thus, there is only one (stable) trajectory which leads to the steady state.
49
dc/dt=0 dk/dt=0 k steady state c
50
Convergence Do income differences decrease or increase (convergence or divergence)? Solow model predicts that income levels decrease (poor countries catch up rich countries): marginal product of capital is larger On top of that, poor countries may also benefit from adaptation of rich countries’ technology Convergence may occur but depend (also) on other things (conditional convergence)
52
GDP per capita in several countries
57
Walt Rostow’s Take-off periods
58
Vernon’s product cycle
Similar presentations
© 2024 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.