Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published byTyrone Powell Modified over 9 years ago
1
Beyond Routing Games: Network (Formation) Games
2
Network Games (NG) NG model the various ways in which selfish users (i.e., players) strategically interact in using a (either communication, computer, social, etc.) network The Internet routing game is a particular type of network congestion game Other examples of NG: social network games, network design games, network creation games, graphical games, etc. Notice that each of these games is actually a class of games, where any element of the class is an instance of the game
3
A warming-up NG: The ISPs dilemma Two Internet Service Providers (ISP) owning part of a network: ISP1 e ISP2 ISP1 wants to send traffic from s1 to t1 ISP2 wants to send traffic from s2 to t2 s1 s2 t1 t2 C S Long links incur a per-user cost of 1 to the ISP owning the link C, S: peering points Each ISP can use two paths: either passing through C or not Short links incur a negligible per-user cost to the ISP owning the link
4
A (bad) DSE s1 s2 t1 t2 C S C, S: peering points avoid C through C avoid C 2, 25, 1 through C 1, 54, 4 Cost Matrix ISP1 ISP2 PoA is (4+4)/(2+2)=2 Dominant Strategy Equilibrium
5
Network Formation Games (NFG) NFG are NG that aim to capture two competing issues for players when using a network for communication purposes: to minimize the afforded cost to be provided with a high quality of service Two big categories of NFG: Network Design Games (a.k.a. Global Connection Games): Users autonomously design a communication subnetwork embedded in an already existing network with the selfish goal of sharing costs in using it for a point-to-point communication Network Creation Games (a.k.a. Local Connection Games): Users autonomously form ex-novo a network that connects them for reciprocal communication (e.g., downloading files in P2P networks, exchanging messages in social networks, etc.)
6
First case study: Network Design Games (a.k.a. Global Connection Games)
7
Introduction A GCG is a game that models the design of a communication subnetwork embedded in a given network (i.e., a graph) for a point-to-point communication, with the selfish goal of sharing costs while using it Players: pay for the links they personally use benefit from sharing links with other players in the selected subnetwork
8
The model G=(V,E): directed graph, k players c e : non-negative cost of e E Player i has a source node s i and a sink node t i Strategy for player i: a path P i from s i to t i Let k e denote the load of edge e, i.e., the number of players using e. The cost of P i for player i in S=(P 1,…,P k ) is shared with all the other players using (part of) it, namely: cost i (S) = c e /k e ePiePi this cost-sharing scheme is called fair or Shapley cost-sharing mechanism
9
The model Given a strategy vector S, the constructed network N(S) is given by the union of all paths P i Then, the social-choice function (i.e., the total cost of the constructed network) is the following : Notice that each user has a favorable effect on the performance of other users (so-called cross monotonicity), as opposed to the congestion model of selfish routing C(S)= cost i (S) = c e /k e = c e ePiePi ii e N(S)
10
Setting What is a stable network? We use NE as the solution concept How to evaluate the overall quality of a stable network? We compare its cost to that of an optimal (in general, unstable) network Our goal: to bound the efficiency loss resulting from selfishness
11
Bounding the loss of efficiency Remind that a network is optimal or socially efficient if it minimizes the social cost (i.e., it minimizes the social-choice function) We use the PoA to estimate the loss of efficiency we may have in the worst case, as given by the ratio between the cost of a worst stable network and the cost of an optimal network What about the ratio between the cost of a best stable network and the cost of an optimal network?
12
The price of stability (PoS) Definition (Schulz & Moses, 2003) : Given a (single-instance) game G and a social-choice function C which depends on the payoff of all the players, let S be the set of all NE. If the payoff represents a cost (resp., a utility) for a player, let OPT be the outcome of G minimizing (resp., maximizing) C. Then, the Price of Stability (PoS) of G w.r.t. C is: Remark: If the game consists of several instances, then its PoS is the maximum/minimum among the PoS of all the instances, depending on whether the payoff for a player is either a cost or a utility. PoS G (C) =
13
Some remarks PoA and PoS are (for positive s.c.f. C) 1 for minimization problems 1 for maximization problems PoA and PoS are small when they are close to 1 PoS is at least as close to 1 than PoA In a game with a unique NE, PoA=PoS Why to study the PoS? sometimes a nontrivial bound is possible only for PoS PoS quantifies the necessary degradation in quality under the game-theoretic constraint of stability
14
An example 1 1 1 1 3 3 3 2 4 5.5 s1s1 s2s2 t1t1 t2t2
15
An example 1 1 1 1 3 3 3 2 45.5 s1s1 s2s2 t1t1 t2t2 optimal network has cost 12 cost 1 =7 cost 2 =5 is it stable?
16
An example 1 1 1 1 3 3 3 2 45.5 s1s1 s2s2 t1t1 t2t2 PoA 13/12, PoS ≤ 13/12 cost 1 =5 cost 2 =8 is it stable? …yes, and has cost 13! …no!, player 1 can decrease its cost
17
An example 1 1 1 1 3 3 3 2 45.5 s1s1 s2s2 t1t1 t2t2 the social cost is 12.5 PoS = 12.5/12 cost 1 =5 cost 2 =7.5 …a best possible NE: Homework: find a worst possible NE
18
Our concerned issues in GCG Does a stable network always exist? Does the repeated version of the game always converge to a stable network? Can we bound the price of anarchy (PoA)? Can we bound the price of stability (PoS)?
19
Any instance of the global connection game has a pure Nash equilibrium, and best response dynamics always converges. Theorem 1 The PoA in the global connection game with k players is at most k (i.e., every instance of the game has PoA ≤ k), and this is tight (i.e., we can exhibit an instance of the game whose PoA is k). Theorem 2 The PoS in the global connection game with k players is at most H k, the k-th harmonic number (i.e., every instance of the game has PoS ≤ H k ), and this is tight (i.e., we can exhibit an instance of the game whose PoS is H k ) Theorem 3
20
For any finite game, an exact potential function is a function that maps every strategy vector S to some real value and satisfies the following condition: The potential function method S=(s 1,…,s k ), s’ i s i, let S’=(s 1,…,s’ i,…,s k ), then (S)- (S’) = cost i (S)-cost i (S’). A game that does possess an exact potential function is called potential game
21
Every potential game has at least one pure Nash equilibrium, namely the strategy vector S that minimizes (S). Lemma 1 Proof: consider any move by a player i that results in a new strategy vector S’. Since (S) is minimum, we have: (S)- (S’) = cost i (S)-cost i (S’) 0 cost i (S) cost i (S’) player i cannot decrease its cost, thus S is a NE.
22
In any finite potential game, best response dynamics always converges to a Nash equilibrium Lemma 2 Observation: any state S with the property that (S) cannot be decreased by changing any single component of S is a NE by the same argument. Furthermore, by definition, improving moves for players decrease the value of the potential function. Together, these observations imply the following result. Convergence in potential games However, it can be shown that converging to a NE may take an exponential (in the number of players) number of steps!
23
…turning our attention to the global connection game… Let be the following function mapping any strategy vector S to a real value [Rosenthal 1973]: (S) = e N(S) e (S) where (recall that k e is the number of players using e) e (S) = c e · H = c e · (1+1/2+…+1/k e ). keke
24
Let S=(P 1,…,P k ), let P’ i be an alternative path for some player i, and define a new strategy vector S’=(S -i,P’ i ). Then: Lemma 3 ( is a potential function) (S) - (S’) = cost i (S) – cost i (S’). Proof: When player i switches from P i to P’ i, some edges of N(S) increase their load by 1, some others decrease it by 1, and the remaining do not change it. Then, it suffices to notice that: If load of edge e increases by 1, its contribution to the potential function increases by c e /(k e +1) If load of edge e decreases by 1, its contribution to the potential function decreases by c e /k e (S) - (S’) = (S) - (S-P i +P’ i ) = (S) – ( (S) - e P i c e /k e + e P’ i c e /(k e +1))= cost i (S) – cost i (S’).
25
Any instance of the global connection game has a pure Nash equilibrium, and best response dynamics always converges. Theorem 1 Proof: From Lemma 3, a GCG is a potential game, and from Lemma 1 and 2 best response dynamics converges to a pure NE. Existence of a NE However, it can be shown that finding a best response for a player is NP-hard!
26
Price of Anarchy: a lower bound s 1,…,s k t 1,…,t k k 1 optimal network has cost 1 best NE: all players use the lower edge worst NE: all players use the upper edge PoS is 1 PoA is k
27
Upper-bounding the PoA The price of anarchy in the global connection game with k players is at most k. Theorem 2 Proof: Let OPT=(P 1 *,…,P k * ) denote the optimal network, and let i be a shortest path in G between s i and t i. Let w( i ) be the length of such a path, and let S be any NE. Observe that cost i (S) ≤w( i ) (otherwise the player i would change). Then: C(S) = cost i (S) ≤ w( i ) ≤ w(P i * ) ≤ k·cost i (OPT) = k· C(OPT). i=1 k k k k (since a path is used by at most k players)
28
PoS for GCG: a lower bound 1+ ... 1 1/2 1/(k-1) 1/k 1/3 0 000 0 s1s1 sksk s2s2 s3s3 s k-1 t 1,…,t k >o: small value
29
1+ ... 1 1/2 1/(k-1) 1/k 1/3 0 000 0 s1s1 sksk s2s2 s3s3 s k-1 t 1,…,t k >o: small value The optimal solution has a cost of 1+ is it stable? PoS for GCG: a lower bound
30
1+ ... 1 1/2 1/(k-1) 1/k 1/3 0 000 0 s1s1 sksk s2s2 s3s3 s k-1 t 1,…,t k >o: small value …no! player k can decrease its cost… is it stable? PoS for GCG: a lower bound
31
1+ ... 1 1/2 1/(k-1) 1/k 1/3 0 000 0 s1s1 sksk s2s2 s3s3 s k-1 t 1,…,t k >o: small value …no! player k-1 can decrease its cost… is it stable? PoS for GCG: a lower bound
32
1+ ... 1 1/2 1/(k-1) 1/k 1/3 0 000 0 s1s1 sksk s2s2 s3s3 s k-1 t 1,…,t k >o: small value The only stable network social cost: C(S)= 1/j = H k ln k + 1 k-th harmonic number j=1 k PoS for GCG: a lower bound
33
Suppose that we have a potential game with potential function , and assume that for any outcome S we have Lemma 4 Proof: Let S’ be the strategy vector minimizing (i.e., S’ is a NE) we have: (S’) (S*) C(S)/A (S) B C(S) for some A,B>0. Then the price of stability is at most AB. Let S* be the strategy vector minimizing the social cost B C(S*) C(S’)/A PoS ≤ C(S’)/C(S*) ≤ A·B.
34
Lemma 5 (Bounding ) C(S) (S) H k C(S). For any strategy vector S in the GCG, we have: (S) = e N(S) e (S) = e N(S) c e · H k e Proof: Indeed: (S) C(S) = e N(S) c e and (S) ≤ H k · C(S) = e N(S) c e · H k.
35
The price of stability in the global connection game with k players is at most H k, the k-th harmonic number. Theorem 3 Proof: From Lemma 3, a GCG is a potential game, and from Lemma 5 and Lemma 4 (with A=1 and B=H k ), its PoS is at most H k. Upper-bounding the PoS
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.