Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published byVerity Robertson Modified over 9 years ago
1
Projektseminar Computational Social Choice -Eine Einführung- Jörg Rothe & Lena Schend SS 2012, HHU Düsseldorf 4. April 2012
2
Introduction Social Choice Theory voting theory preference aggregation judgment aggregation Computer Science artificial intelligence algorithm design computational complexity theory - worst-case/average-case complexity - optimization, etc. voting in multiagent systems multi-criteria decision making meta search, etc.... Software agents can systematically analyze elections to find optimal strategies
3
Introduction Social Choice Theory voting theory preference aggregation judgment aggregation Computational Social Choice Computer Science artificial intelligence algorithm design computational complexity theory - worst-case/average-case complexity - optimization, etc. computational barriers to prevent manipulation control bribery Software agents can systematically analyze elections to find optimal strategies
4
Computational Social Choice With the power of NP-hardness vulcans have constructed complexity shields to protect elections against many types of manipulation and control.
5
Computational Social Choice With the power of NP-hardness vulcans have constructed complexity shields to protect elections against many types of manipulation and control. Question: Are worst-case complexity shields enough? Or do they evaporate on "typical elections"?
6
NP-Hardness Shields Evaporating? NP-hardness shields single-peaked electorates junta distributions approximation experimental analysis
7
Elections An election is a pair (C,V) with a finite set C of candidates: a finite list V of voters. Voters are represented by their preferences over C: either by linear orders: > > > or by approval vectors: (1,1,0,1) Voting system: determines winners from the preferences
8
Voting Systems Approval Voting (AV) votes are approval vectors in v1v1 1101 v2v2 0100 v3v3 1101 v4v4 0010 v5v5 1011 v6v6 1001
9
Voting Systems Approval Voting (AV) votes are approval vectors in winners: all candidates with the most approvals v1v1 1101 v2v2 0100 v3v3 1101 v4v4 0010 v5v5 1011 v6v6 1001 ∑ 4324
10
Voting Systems Approval Voting (AV) votes are approval vectors in winners: all candidates with the most approvals winners: v1v1 1101 v2v2 0100 v3v3 1101 v4v4 0010 v5v5 1011 v6v6 1001 ∑ 4324
11
Voting Systems Positional Scoring Rules (for m candidates) defined by scoring vector with each voter gives points to the candidate on position i winners: all candidates with maximum score Borda:Plurality Voting (PV): k-Approval (m-k-Veto):Veto (Anti-Plurality):
12
-4:02:23:1 0:4-1:32:2 3:1-2:2 1:32:2 - Voting Systems Pairwise Comparison v 1 : >>> v 3 : > > > v 2 : >>> v 4 : > > > Condorcet: beats all other candidates strictly Copeland : 1 point for victory points for tie Maximin: maximum of the worst pairwise comparison
13
Voting Systems Round-based: Single Transferable Vote (STV) v 1 : >>> v 2 : > > > v 3 : > >> v 4 : > > > Round 1 over eliminate cand. with lowest plurality score Round 2 over eliminate cand. with lowest plurality score Final Round over eliminate cand. with lowest plurality score
14
Voting Systems Round-based: Single Transferable Vote (STV) v 1 : >> v 2 : > > v 3 : > > v 4 : > > Round 1 over eliminate cand. with lowest plurality score Round 2 over eliminate cand. with lowest plurality score Final Round over eliminate cand. with lowest plurality score
15
Voting Systems Round-based: Single Transferable Vote (STV) v 1 : v 2 : v 3 : v 4 : Round 1 over eliminate cand. with lowest plurality score Round 2 over eliminate cand. with lowest plurality score Final Round over … and the winner is…
16
Voting Systems Level-based: Bucklin Voting (BV) v 1 : > > > v 2 : > > > v 3 : > > > v 4 : > > > v 5 : > > > 5 voters => strict majority threshold is 3 Lvl 11220
17
Voting Systems Level-based: Bucklin Voting (BV) v 1 : > > > v 2 : > > > v 3 : > > > v 4 : > > > v 5 : > > > 5 voters => strict majority threshold is 3 Lvl 11220 Lvl 22233
18
Voting Systems Level-based: Bucklin Voting (BV) v 1 : > > > v 2 : > > > v 3 : > > > v 4 : > > > Level 2 Bucklin v 5 : > > > winners: 5 voters => strict majority threshold is 3 Lvl 11220 Lvl 22233
19
Voting Systems Level-based: Fallback Voting (FV) combines AV and BV Candidates: v: {, } | {, } v: > | {, } Bucklin winners are fallback winners. If no Bucklin winner exists (due to disapprovals), then approval winners win.
20
War on Electoral Control AV winners: "chair": knows all preferences v1v1 1101 v2v2 0100 v3v3 1101 v4v4 0010 v5v5 1011 v6v6 1001 ∑ 4324
21
War on Electoral Control AV winner: "chair": knows all preferences and can change the structure of an election v1v1 1101 v2v2 0100 v3v3 1101 v4v4 0010 v5v5 1011 v6v6 1001 ∑ 2312
22
War on Electoral Control AV winner: "chair": knows all preferences and can change the structure Other types of control: of an election adding/partitioning voters deleting/adding/partitioning candidates v1v1 1101 v2v2 0100 v3v3 1101 v4v4 0010 v5v5 1011 v6v6 1001 ∑ 2312
23
NP-Hardness Shields for Control Resistance = NP-hardness, Vulnerability = P, Immunity, and Susceptibility
24
Cope- land Score -4:02:23:12.5 0:4-1:32:20.5 2:23:1-2:22 1:32:2 -1 War on Manipulation Copeland : winner v 1 : >>> v 3 : > > > v 2 : >>> v 4 : > > > I like Spock but I don‘t want him to be the captain!!
25
Copeland : winner v 1 : >>> v 3 : > > > v 2 : >>> v 4 : > > > assumption:. v 4 knows the other voters‘ votes v 4 lies to make his most preferred candidate win Cope- land Score -4:02:23:12.5 0:4-1:32:20.5 2:23:1-2:22 1:32:2 -1 War on Manipulation I like Spock but I don‘t want him to be the captain!!
26
Copeland : winners v 1 : >>> v 3 : > > > v 2 : >>> v 4 : > > > Here: unweighted voters, single manipulator. Other types: - coalitional manipulation - weighted voters Cope- land Score -3:12:2 2 1:3- 0 2:23:1-2:22 3:12:2-2 War on Manipulation I like Spock but I don‘t want him to be the captain!!
27
NP-Hardness Shields for Manipulation Results due to Conitzer, Sandholm, Lang (J.ACM 2007)
28
NP-Hardness Shields Evaporating? NP-hardness shields single-peaked electorates junta distributions approximation experimental analysis
29
Junta Distributions of Procaccia and Rosenschein (JAAMAS 2007) are omitted here, as they are a rather technical concept.
30
NP-Hardness Shields Evaporating? NP-hardness shields single-peaked electorates junta distributions approximation experimental analysis
31
Experiments Manipulation testing (heuristic) algorithms for manipulation problem at hand on given elections sample real elections generate random elections: Impartial Culture (IC) Polya-Eggenberger (PE) voters vote independently all preferences are equally likely voters are highly correlated v 1 v 2 v 3... Walsh (IJCAI 2009; ECAI 2010)
32
Experiments Manipulation testing (heuristic) algorithms for manipulation problem at hand on given elections sample real elections generate random elections: Impartial Culture (IC) Polya-Eggenberger (PE) voters vote independently all preferences are equally likely voters are highly correlated v 1 v 2 v 3... Walsh (IJCAI 2009; ECAI 2010)
33
Experiments Manipulation testing (heuristic) algorithms for manipulation problem at hand on given elections sample real elections generate random elections: Impartial Culture (IC) Polya-Eggenberger (PE) voters vote independently all preferences are equally likely voters are highly correlated v 1 v 2 v 3... Walsh (IJCAI 2009; ECAI 2010)
34
Experiments Manipulation testing (heuristic) algorithms for manipulation problem at hand on given elections sample real elections generate random elections: Impartial Culture (IC) Polya-Eggenberger (PE) voters vote independently all preferences are equally likely voters are highly correlated v 1 v 2 v 3... Walsh (IJCAI 2009; ECAI 2010)
35
Experiments Manipulation testing (heuristic) algorithms for manipulation problem at hand on given elections sample real elections generate random elections: Impartial Culture (IC) Polya-Eggenberger (PE) voters vote independently all preferences are equally likely voters are highly correlated v 1 v 2 v 3... Walsh (IJCAI 2009; ECAI 2010)
36
Experiments Manipulation testing (heuristic) algorithms for manipulation problem at hand on given elections sample real elections generate random elections: Impartial Culture (IC) Polya-Eggenberger (PE) voters vote independently all preferences are equally likely voters are highly correlated v 1 v 2 v 3... Walsh (IJCAI 2009; ECAI 2010)
37
Experiments Manipulation Results for STV Single Manipulation: for up to 128 candidates/voters manipulation has low computational costs (for all voter distributions) chance of successful manipulation decreases with increasing number of nonmanipulative voters Coalitional Manipulation: larger coalitions are more likely to be successful again: computational costs are low for up to 128 candidates/voters Results for Veto (weighted) if manipulators‘ weights are too big/small => trivial even in critical region: computational costs are low only correlated voters increase computational costs Walsh (IJCAI 2009; ECAI 2010)
38
NP-Hardness Shields Evaporating? NP-hardness shields single-peaked electorates junta distributions approximation experimental analysis
39
Approximating Manipulation Before: Is manipulation possible?
40
Approximating Manipulation Before: Is manipulation possible? Now: How many manipulators are needed? (min!) Approximation Algorithms: -efficient algorithms -do not always find optimal solution -can be analyzed both theoretically and experimentally
41
Approximating Borda 3x > > > > > > 2x > > > > > > Borda winner manipulators prefer B-Score 501819202122
42
Approximating Borda Algorithm for Borda-CCUM : "Reverse" m 1 > > > > > > B-Score 501819202122 Zuckerman, Procaccia & Rosenschein (Artificial Intelligence 2009)
43
Approximating Borda Algorithm for Borda-CCUM : "Reverse" m 1 > > > > > > B-Score 11522 Zuckerman, Procaccia & Rosenschein (Artificial Intelligence 2009)
44
Approximating Borda Algorithm for Borda-CCUM : "Reverse" m 1 > > > > > > m 2 > > > > > > B-Score 11522 Zuckerman, Procaccia & Rosenschein (Artificial Intelligence 2009)
45
Approximating Borda Algorithm for Borda-CCUM : "Reverse" m 1 > > > > > > m 2 > > > > > > B-Score 17102625242322 Zuckerman, Procaccia & Rosenschein (Artificial Intelligence 2009)
46
Approximating Borda Algorithm for Borda-CCUM : "Reverse" m 1 > > > > > > m 2 > > > > > > m 3 > > > > > > B-Score 17102625242322 Zuckerman, Procaccia & Rosenschein (Artificial Intelligence 2009)
47
Approximating Borda Algorithm for Borda-CCUM : "Reverse" m 1 > > > > > > m 2 > > > > > > m 3 > > > > > > B-Score 231526 Zuckerman, Procaccia & Rosenschein (Artificial Intelligence 2009)
48
Approximating Borda Algorithm for Borda-CCUM : "Reverse" m 1 > > > > > > m 2 > > > > > > m 3 > > > > > > m 4 > > > > > > B-Score 231526 Zuckerman, Procaccia & Rosenschein (Artificial Intelligence 2009)
49
Approximating Borda Algorithm for Borda-CCUM : "Reverse" m 1 > > > > > > m 2 > > > > > > m 3 > > > > > > m 4 > > > > > > B-Score 29203029282726 Zuckerman, Procaccia & Rosenschein (Artificial Intelligence 2009)
50
Approximating Borda Algorithm for Borda-CCUM : "Reverse" m 1 > > > > > > m 2 > > > > > > m 3 > > > > > > m 4 > > > > > > m 5 > > > > > > B-Score 29203029282726 Zuckerman, Procaccia & Rosenschein (Artificial Intelligence 2009)
51
Approximating Borda Algorithm for Borda-CCUM : "Reverse" m 1 > > > > > > m 2 > > > > > > m 3 > > > > > > m 4 > > > > > > m 5 > > > > > > B-Score 352530 Zuckerman, Procaccia & Rosenschein (Artificial Intelligence 2009)
52
Approximating Borda Optimal solution: 4 manipulators m 1 > > > > > > m 2 > > > > > > m 3 > > > > > > m 4 > > > > > > "Reverse" needs one manipulator more than optimal B-Score 292028 Zuckerman, Procaccia & Rosenschein (Artificial Intelligence 2009)
53
Approximation Results Maximin: factor 2 (twice number of optimal manipulators) factor 5/3 (not better than 3/2 unless P=NP) Borda: Reverse: additional 1 Largest Fit unbounded additional number Average Fit of manipulators,, and are theoretically incomparable experimental comparison: IC model 76%83%99% PE model 76%43%99% Zuckerman, Lev & Rosenschein (AAMAS 2011) Davies, Katsirelos, Narodytska & Walsh (AAAI 2011)
54
NP-Hardness Shields Evaporating? NP-hardness shields single-peaked electorates junta distributions approximation experimental analysis
55
Single-Peaked Preferences A collection V of votes is said to be single-peaked if there exists a linear order L over C such that each voter‘s „degree of preference“ rises to a peak and then falls (or just rises or just falls). A voter‘s preference curve on galactic taxes low galactic taxes high galactic taxes
56
A collection V of votes is said to be single-peaked if there exists a linear order L over C such that each voter‘s „degree of preference“ rises to a peak and then falls (or just rises or just falls). A voter‘s > > > preference curve on galactic taxes low galactic taxes high galactic taxes Single-Peaked Preferences Single-peaked preference consistent with linear order of candidates
57
A collection V of votes is said to be single-peaked if there exists a linear order L over C such that each voter‘s „degree of preference“ rises to a peak and then falls (or just rises or just falls). A voter‘s > > > preference curve on galactic taxes low galactic taxes high galactic taxes Single-Peaked Preferences Preference that is inconsistent with this linear order of candidates
58
Single-Peaked Preferences A collection V of votes is said to be single-peaked if there exists a linear order L over C such that each voter‘s „degree of preference“ rises to a peak and then falls (or just rises or just falls). If each vote v i in V is a linear order > i over C, this means that for each triple of candidates c, d, and e: (c L d L e or e L d L c) implies that for each i, if c > i d then d > i e.
59
Single-Peaked Preferences A collection V of votes is said to be single-peaked if there exists a linear order L over C such that each voter‘s „degree of preference“ rises to a peak and then falls (or just rises or just falls). If each vote v i in V is a linear order > i over C, this means that for each triple of candidates c, d, and e: (c L d L e or e L d L c) implies that for each i, if c > i d then d > i e. Bartholdi & Trick (1986); Escoffier, Lang & Öztürk (2008): Given a collection V of linear orders over C, in polynomial time we can produce a linear order L witnessing V‘s single- peakedness or can determine that V is not single-peaked.
60
A collection V of votes is said to be single-peaked if there exists a linear order L over C such that each voter‘s „degree of preference“ rises to a peak and then falls (or just rises or just falls). Single-peaked w.r.t. this order? v1v1 11001no v2v2 01100yes v3v3 11001no v4v4 00010yes v5v5 10011no v6v6 10001 Single-Peaked Approval Vectors
61
Removing NP-hardness shields: 3-candidate Borda veto every scoring protocol for -candidate 3-veto, Leaving them in place: STV (Walsh AAAI 2007) 4-candidate Borda 5-candidate 3-veto Erecting NP-hardness shields: Artificial election system with approval votes, for size-3-coalition unweighted manipulation Results due to Faliszewski, Hemaspaandra, Hemaspaandra & Rothe (Information & Computation 2011) GeneralSingle-peaked Constructive Coalitional Weighted Manipulation
62
Removing NP-hardness shields: Approval Constructive control by adding voters Constructive control by deleting voters Plurality constructive control by adding candidates destructive control by adding candidates constructive control by deleting candidates destructive control by deleting candidates Results due to Faliszewski, Hemaspaandra, Hemaspaandra & Rothe (2011) Brandt, Brill, Hemaspaandra & Hemaspaandra (AAAI 2010) achieved similar results for other voting systems as well (e.g., for systems satisfying the weak Condorcet criterion) and also for constructive control by partition of voters. GeneralSingle-peaked Control for Single-Peaked Electorates
63
More Results on Single-Peaked Preferences Faliszewski, Hemaspaandra, Hemaspaandra & Rothe (2011) also prove a dichotomy result for the scoring protocol CCWM is NP-complete if and in P otherwise. Brandt, Brill, Hemaspaandra & Hemaspaandra (AAAI 2010) generalize this dichotomoy to scoring protocols with any fixed number of candidates. Mattei (ADT 2011) empirically investigates huge data sets from real-world elections (drawn from the Netflix Prize) and observes that single-peaked preferences very rarely occur in practice. Faliszewski, Hemaspaandra & Hemaspaandra (TARK 2011) study manipulative attacks in nearly single-peaked electorates.
64
NP-Hardness Shields Evaporating? NP-hardness shields single-peaked electorates junta distributions approximation experimental analysis
65
Experiments Control same approach as for manipulation testing (heuristic) algorithms for control problem at hand on given elections sample real elections generate random elections: Impartial Culture (IC) Two Mainstreams (TM) voters vote independently all preferences are equally likely voters are correlated
66
Experiments Control same approach as for manipulation testing (heuristic) algorithms for control problem at hand on given elections sample real elections generate random elections: Impartial Culture (IC) Two Mainstreams (TM) voters vote independently all preferences are equally likely voters are correlated
67
Experiments Control same approach as for manipulation testing (heuristic) algorithms for control problem at hand on given elections sample real elections generate random elections: Impartial Culture (IC) Two Mainstreams (TM) voters vote independently all preferences are equally likely voters are correlated v 1 v 2 v 3 v 4...
68
Experiments Control Observations: destructive control shows more yes-instances (up to 100%) and lower computational costs DCPV-TP in FV
69
Experiments Control Observations: destructive control shows more yes-instances (up to 100%) and lower computational costs CCPV-TP in FV
70
Experiments Control Observations: destructive control shows more yes-instances (up to 100%) and lower computational costs FV and BV show similar tendencies voter control in PV has lower computational costs deleting/adding voters show similar tendencies for constructive control: voter control shows more yes-instances than candidate control as expected: more yes-instances in the IC model than in the TM model
71
Thank you very much! That‘s typical for you humans! Please wait until the talk ist finished before you start asking questions!
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.