Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published byKerry Newman Modified over 9 years ago
1
26.04.20051 Lecture 12: Economic incentives and the organization of private physician practice II
2
2 A GP’s optimal number of patients and level of service provision Reference: Iversen 2004 Problem to be addressed: Irrespective of whether a formal list patient system exists, a GP will often have a group of people who visit him regularly and consider him to be their personal doctor. An important decision for the GP is: How many people would he like to care for and what level of service provision would he like to offer? These decision also implicitly contains the choice of income and leisure. Are these decisions influenced by the payment system a GP is offered? For instance: Are there other incentives in a capitation fee compared with a fee for service? And what about combinations?
3
3 For a number of GP consultations it is not clear what constitutes "the right medical treatment". In terms of McGuires notation: We don’t know for sure the B(x) Time interval between regular checkups Follow-up consultation Referral rates An interesting consequence of the lack of medical standards is that several practice profiles are all regarded as equally satisfactory from a professional point of view A ‘grey area’, [ , + ], where a health service, s i, does not have any documented effect on health at the margin, h(s i )=0.
4
4 Assume that the number of services per patient will be somewhere in this interval We assume that the physician can influence the number of patients (n) he takes care of. We assume that a physician decides the quantity of health services provided to each of his patients. We further assume that a physician has lexicographic preferences concerning his patients’ health and his own income and leisure. This assumption implies that a patient’s health is never balanced against the GP’s income or leisure. Health services are then provided until the marginal health effect is equal to zero. The implication of relaxing this assumption? We assume a quasilinear objective function formulated in monetary terms as V = c + v(l), where c is consumption (all income is consumed) and l is leisure. v(l) is assumed to be strictly concave with v'(l) > 0. Problem: What is the a GP’s optimal combination of patients and number of services per patient? The physician’s decision problem may formally be expressed as:
5
5 w is a fixed salary or practice allowance q is a capitation payment per person on the physician’s list of patients p is the fee per item of health service (or equivalently, a fee for service) s is the level of accessibility C(s) is a cost of providing access unrelated to the number of consultations, C’>0, C’’>0 t(s) is the time input of providing health service depending on s, t’>0, t’’>0 T is the total time endowment (i)says that the number of services provided to a patient must be within the interval where the marginal effect of services on health is not documented to be different from zero. (ii) says that the number of patients is less or equal to the demand for being added to the GP’s list, where S is a vector of access offered by other GPs in the area, is a vector of exogenously determined characteristics of the GP as perceived by (potential) patients, and is a vector that describes similar characteristics of other GPs in the area. N is the number of residents in the area and M is the number of GPs. We shall only consider cases where n is positive.
6
6 Let us now for a moment simplify the model by assuming s fixed and n d ()= We then have: The GP’s optimum depends on the payment system he works under. The maximization problem can be analyzed by means of non-linear programming Here, a bit less formal …..
7
7 A. Fixed Salary: w>0, q=p=0: Needs a constraint on l ; l ≤ l 0 Number of working hours part of the employment contract Needs to introduce some kind of community responsibility, work ethics and/or dedication to the work The model not so suitable for predictions about fixed salary
8
8 B. Per capita fee: w=p=0; q>0: Assume an interior solution (ineffective constraints):
9
9 From (2): Marginal income of patients equal to marginal costs in terms of reduced leisure. What if n=n 0 ; i.e. effective constraint: Patient shortage “Too much leisure”
10
10 C. Fee for service: w=q=0; p>0 Assume interior solution
11
11 What if the constraint n=n 0 is effective? Forced leisure – patient shortage: (AC) Combination practice allowance/fee for service: w>0, p>0, q=0: No influence on FOC from (C) (BC) Combination per capita fee/fee for service: w>0, p>0, q=0: Show that we still have k=0 as the optimal solution: Still more rewarding with additional patients than additional services Hint: Assume an interior solution (0<k<β) and show that FOC then contain a contradiction. Show also that n is determined from q + pα = v’(l)αt Marginal income from patients equals marginal cost of reduced leisure
12
12 (AC) Combination practice allowance/fee for service: w>0, p>0, q=0: No influence on FOC from (C) (BC) Combination per capita fee/fee for service: w>0, p>0, q=0: Show that we still have k=0 as the optimal solution: Still more rewarding with additional patients than additional services Show that n is determined from q + pα = v’(l)αt Marginal income from patients equals marginal cost of reduced leisure
13
13 Questions: What are the expected effects of an increase in the number of GPs on provision of services under the various payment systems? What are the effect of the introduction of a capitation system, for instance from (AC) to (BC) on a GP’s optimal number of patients? What about the number of services? Consider the impact on previous conclusions of assuming that n d is not longer fixed, but may depend on s (accessibility) and k (service intensity)?
14
14 Example: Denmark: The change in payment system for GPs in Copenhagen Krasnik, A. et al., 1990, Changing remuneration systems: effects on activity in general practice, British Medical Journal 300, 1698-1701. Stæhr Johansen, A. K., 1995, Primary care in Denmark, in A. Alban and T. Christiansen, eds., The Nordic lights. New initiatives in health care systems (Odense University Press, Odense) 81-105. Objective: To study the effects on GPs activities of a change in their remuneration system from a capitation based system to a mixed capitation and fee per item based system. What would we expect? Central features of the study design: Before October 1987: GPs in the City of Copenhagen were paid on a capitation basis From October 1987: GPs in the City of Copenhagen were paid according to the same system as the GPs in the rest of Denmark
15
15 The behaviour of 100 GPs in the City of Copenhagen and 326 GPs in Copenhagen county was studied GPs behaviour was measured in three periods: March 1987, March 1988, November 1988. Central results of the study –No increase in the number of consultations –Increase in diagnostic services –Increase in curative services –Decrease in referrals to specialists –Decrease in referral to hospitals Conclusions: The amount of services provided increased after the introduction of the fee for service component. The number of consultations, that are partly patient initiated, did not increase.
16
16 Example 2: Main results from Iversen (2004) Data from the Norwegian capitation trial (1993-1996) that preceded the capitation reform Four municipalities with 250 000 inhabitants Some GPs got a shorter list of patients that they preferred at the start of the trial Problem studied: Does this shortage of patients have any impact of their intensity of services provision Similar studies are now going on with data for the whole country after the capitation reform
17
17 Model 1Model 2 Propfem132.4(87.6)160.2*(43.0) Propold327.3*(112.5)300.0*(59.7) Time9.3*(1.9)10.4*(2.5) Municip2-57.1(32.2)-59.2*(26.1) Municip3-76.0*(27.0)-77.6*(20.9) Municip4-109.9*(28.7)-112.7*(22.4) Salaried16.6(14.4)18.5*(8.5) Ration33.5*(13.0)32.2*(7.7) Female-30.3(23.9)-38.1*(13.7) Constant178.3*(49.2)168.9*(31.9) ρAρA 0.510.42 R2R2 0.280.29 Number of observations 489 From the reading list: Table 3: The estimated effect of a shortage of patients on income per listed person (INPERCAP) (standard errors in parenthesis)
18
18 From the evaluation of the capitation reform in Norway
19
19
20
20 From the evaluation of the capitation reform in Norway
21
21
22
22 Preliminary results from the evaluation of the capitation system in Norway show: Average income per list person from fees from National insurance: NOK 473 Results from regression analyses adjusted for list composition and indicators of accessibility: A shortage of patients increases income from fees per listed person with (72/473)x100% = 15% A shortage of patients increases consultations per 1000 listed people per month with (26/213)x100% = 12% A shortage of patients increases consultations per 1000 listed people per month with(9/61)x100% = 15%
23
23 Policy implications: Physician and practice characteristics have an impact on the number and type of services provided and on the public expenditures per person listed Patient shortage is costly to the insurer because of income motivated behavior by GPs with unknown benefit to the patient The income motivated behavior is driven by the fee-for- service component An alternative would be to drop the fee for service component and let the payment system be based on the capitation fee only. The GPs would then compete for patients without considering the income from services per se. Services delivered would then be a means to attract patients to the list and hence, to generate capitation income. The problem is that under a pure capitation system not all patients are equally attractive because of variation in need for services. A risk adjustment component would then be required to prevent risk selection by the GPs.
24
24 It is well known from the literature that a risk adjusted capitation system is hard to construct in practice. The present study therefore demonstrates the classical trade off between patient selection and inefficiency in health care. We have so far only considered optimal choice from the physician’s perspective, and have not analyzed the relation to optimal service provision from the society’s point of view. An important challenge for future research is therefore to gain more knowledge of the optimal mix of salary, capitation and fee for service in general practice from the society’s perspective. Do patients prefer the extra services? We do not know. Important to distinguish between rationing of services and Physician Induced Demand (PID). According to McGuire (2000), “Physician- induced demand (PID) exists when the physician influences a patient’s demand for care against the physician’s interpretation of the best interest of the patient”. What we observe is probably a less strict rationing of services among those GPs who have patient shortage. On every list there are probably people who want more frequent and longer consultations. Patients become more satisfied and GPs with patient shortage obtain more income.
25
25 But is the public sector willing to pay for this? The ”extra services” cannot be distinguished from the basic services in the fee schedule Illustrates how difficult it is to direct GPs towards a social optimum by means of economic incentives The importance of practice guidelines. A long way to go: Only a minority of GPs say that they use guidelines from their professional associations and the authorities regularly in their practice.
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.