Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

1 Information Aggregation and Investment Decisions by Elias Albagi, Christian Hellwig, and Aleh Tsyvinnski Comment: Frank Heinemann Technical University.

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "1 Information Aggregation and Investment Decisions by Elias Albagi, Christian Hellwig, and Aleh Tsyvinnski Comment: Frank Heinemann Technical University."— Presentation transcript:

1 1 Information Aggregation and Investment Decisions by Elias Albagi, Christian Hellwig, and Aleh Tsyvinnski Comment: Frank Heinemann Technical University Berlin Asset Prices, Credit and Macroeconomic Policy International Conference Marseilles - March 25-26, 2011

2 2 The Market A firm‘s dividends depend on a normally distributed state variable θ. Risk neutral shareholders (traders) get private signals about the state x i ~ N(θ, 1/β). Call those whose signal is higher than θ „optimistic“. They may hold or sell their asset. There is exogenous asset demand determined by a random variable u. Market price is common knowledge. There are no other traders (arbitrageurs/speculators).

3 3 Equilibrium A trader sells iff her signal is below a threshold x*. Price reveals a compound of θ (=> dividends) and u (=> demand). If price is high, traders partially attribute this to a high state and expect higher dividends. The higher demand, the more traders must sell. The marginal trader is changing and becomes more optimistic. => price rises above expected dividends (conditional on z). Since individual trader does not know her position in the distribution of private signals, she cannot correct this. Low demand => price < expected dividends. => excess volatility!

4 4 Why can‘t a shareholder offset her „mistake“ by taking the expected wedge into account? Marginal trader has a signal that leads her to belief that z is higher than it actually is. She is too optimistic.

5 5 Equilibrium The higher demand, the more traders must sell. Whenever u > 0, the marginal trader is an optimist. The posterior belief of the marginal trader is biased from public information z towards a state with higher expected dividends. This bias increases in u. Positive demand shocks increase optimism and overvaluation w.r.t. exp‘d dividends. Negative demand shocks => undervaluation Note that demand also reflects some market value.

6 6 Firm‘s investment and convexity Firm‘s manager decides on investment, observing share price P(z) and a private signal y on investment costs. RE => Decision rule is foreseen by shareholders. Profitability of investment depends (positively) on θ. => Firm is more likely to invest in good expected states, i.e. for high z(θ,u). acceleration of expected dividends. => Expected dividends are a convex function of z. => Ex ante expected difference between price and fundamental value, E(P(z)) – E(V(z)), is positive.

7 7 Firm‘s investment and convexity With a positive demand shock, the marginal trader („the market“) gets more optimistic and she is willing to pay a higher premium on an investment by the firm than an unbiased risk neutral trader would do. => If manager‘s compensation rises in the share price, he has an incentive to invest, even if the expected reward is below costs. => overinvestment for positive demand shocks underinvestment for negative demand shocks => higher volatility!

8 8 Firm‘s investment overinvestment for positive demand shocks underinvestment for negative demand shocks This reduces ex-ante expected prices and dividends in comparison to a firm with the right investment decisions. This is a bit like Barro/Gordon: a commitment to invest efficiently, given available information, would raise the average price. But since costs are private info of the manager, a commitment is not credible. Hence, manager follows beliefs of „the market“ (= posterior of an optimistic or pessimistic trader).

9 9 An outside observer knows distribution and observes price. Since price function is invertible, he can calculate summary statistic z Wedge P(z) – V(z) depends on z. Outside observer (speculator) should buy, whenever P(z) V(z). QUESTION 1: Is it reasonable to exclude speculation? Q2: Does a trader who neglects her private signal make higher expected profits than a shareholder with additional private information? Is this a „curse of knowledge“? Q3: Could arbitrageurs/speculators be included and results still hold, if one applies „cursed equilibrium“?

10 10 Other questions Role of belief heterogeneity (p. 20): what would results be, if beliefs are identical but noisy? (or distributed around a noisy mean) Introducing arbitrage traders: - what is the optimal trading strategy of an informed trader w/o limits to buy and sell? - what is the optimal trading strategy of an outsider who just observes P(z)?

11 11 Ex-ante perspective Suppose, setting up the firm costs S. These costs are sunk at the time of our game. A rational investor should invest in the firm if E(P) > S. For E(P) > S > E(V) expected returns are below these costs. => A rational investor may setup a firm although its expected return is below the setup-costs. => Overinvestment / bubble / Tobin‘s q. Under which conditions do these phenomena arise here? Macroeconomic consequences? Optimal regulation? Note: Exogenous demand also reflects some welfare components.


Download ppt "1 Information Aggregation and Investment Decisions by Elias Albagi, Christian Hellwig, and Aleh Tsyvinnski Comment: Frank Heinemann Technical University."

Similar presentations


Ads by Google