Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published byJeffry McBride Modified over 9 years ago
1
PPA 723: Managerial Economics Lecture 17: Public Goods The Maxwell School, Syracuse University Professor John Yinger
2
Managerial Economics, Lecture 17: Public Goods Outline Definitions Common Resources Public Goods
3
Managerial Economics, Lecture 17: Public Goods Market Failure Market power (e.g. monopoly) is a market failure that may call for government intervention. Today we start a section on public goods and externalities, which lead to another kind of market failure that may call for government intervention—even in competitive markets. We will look at both positive analysis (how do people behave with public goods and externalities) and normative analysis (the case for government intervention).
4
Managerial Economics, Lecture 17: Public Goods Definitions The topics in this section involve situations in which people interact with each other. Externality = a case in which one person’s actions inadvertently affect other people. Common Property = a case in which many people consume a common resource. Public Good = a good that by its very nature provides benefits to more than one person.
5
Managerial Economics, Lecture 17: Public Goods Schedule Today we look at common property and public goods. Then we have two lectures and a case on externalities.
6
Managerial Economics, Lecture 17: Public Goods Private Goods Private goods are characterized by: Rivalry: only one person can consume the good (it is depletable). Exclusion: others can be prevented from consuming the good. Private goods may also involve externalities.
7
Managerial Economics, Lecture 17: Public Goods Common Property Common property is defined as a resource to which everyone has free access. Examples of common property include Fisheries Public grazing lands Common pools (petroleum, water…) The internet Many roads
8
Managerial Economics, Lecture 17: Public Goods Public Goods Public goods are commodities or services, such as national defense, for which consumption by one person doesn’t preclude consumption by others. In other words, public goods lack rivalry. The nonrivalry in a public good may have a limit; that is, the good may eventually become “congested.”
9
Managerial Economics, Lecture 17: Public Goods Club Good A club good is a public good with exclusion. Examples include a tennis club or a concert: Security guards can keep people who don’t have tickets from entering a concert hall The marginal cost of adding one more person is zero, as long as the hall is not filled (i.e. there is not congestion.)
10
Managerial Economics, Lecture 17: Public Goods Relationships Among Concepts A common property involves a type of externality, namely, the impact of users on the common property. A public good is one characterized by “non- rivalry,” in the sense that it can be provided to more than one person without raising its cost. But many public goods, like common property, are characterized by “non- excludability.” A public good is often said to have a positive externality: because of non-rivalry, providing it to one person provides benefits to others.
11
Managerial Economics, Lecture 17: Public Goods Table 18.03 Rivalry and Exclusion Note: Externalities may exist in the rivalry/exclusion cell and arise by definition in the other three cells.
12
Managerial Economics, Lecture 17: Public Goods The Tragedy of the Commons Common property is a resource to which everyone has free access. Because access is free, people do not consider their impact on the resource when they use it— that is, the social cost they impose. As a result, people over-use the common property, lowering the benefits to society.
13
Managerial Economics, Lecture 17: Public Goods Government Policy for Common Property To avoid over-use, governments sometimes limit usage or place a fee on usage. In the case of fishing, for example, some fishing areas are placed off-limits or allowable catches of certain types of fish are limited. On highways, usage may be controlled with tolls. We return to these policies when we analyze externalities more generally.
14
Managerial Economics, Lecture 17: Public Goods The Demand for Public Goods In the case of a private good, the market demand curve is the horizontal sum of individual demand curves. In the case of a public good, the market demand curve is the vertical sum of the individual demand curves: each additional unit goes to everyone simultaneously. In both cases the market demand curve is the marginal social benefit curve.
15
Managerial Economics, Lecture 17: Public Goods The Demand for a Public Good Price of guard service, $ per hour Guards per hour Supply,MC 25 18 13 10 8 7 3 2 57940 e p e s D 1 D D 2 D = Marginal Social Benefit Curve
16
Managerial Economics, Lecture 17: Public Goods Markets for Public Goods Private markets for public goods exist only if nonpurchasers can be excluded from consuming them. Without the possibility of exclusion, people can be free riders, that is, they can receive the good without paying. A market obviously cannot operate if consumers can choose not to pay!
17
Managerial Economics, Lecture 17: Public Goods Exclusive Public Goods Private markets can exist for exclusive (or excludable) public goods But these markets tend to produce too little of the good because of non-rivalry Microsoft’s marginal cost for one more unit is virtually zero It’s price is much higher!
18
Managerial Economics, Lecture 17: Public Goods Providing Public Goods To ensure that a nonexclusive public good is provided, the government, unlike a private firm, can levy taxes and then Produce it Pay private firms to produce it If the government does not provide it, all the consumer surplus associated with the good is lost.
19
Managerial Economics, Lecture 17: Public Goods Providing Public Goods, 2 A government often has difficulty determining the benefits from a public good. People may not to reveal their willingness to pay (= benefits) if they think their preferences might be linked to their taxes. A government learns these benefits through Surveys Citizens’ votes
20
Managerial Economics, Lecture 17: Public Goods Voting One simple way to think about voting is to recognize that the outcome will always depend on the preferences of the median voter. The median voter is defined as the voter in the middle of the distribution of voter preferences for the public good.
21
Managerial Economics, Lecture 17: Public Goods Example Traffic signal costs $300 to install. There are 3 voters, who will share the cost. Each person votes for the signal only if he or she thinks the signal is worth at least $100 (= the tax each person will pay). There are 3 cases (corners) in the table. In each case, Hayley is median voter, so her views determine the outcome.
22
Managerial Economics, Lecture 17: Public Goods
23
Voting and Efficiency It is efficient to provide public good if the aggregate benefit (that is, the sum of the benefits to all households) is greater than the cost. This is about allocative efficiency. Majority voting may not lead to efficiency; Voting gives each person equal weight; An efficiency calculation gives each dollar of willingness to pay equal weight.
24
Managerial Economics, Lecture 17: Public Goods The Tiebout Hypothesis Local public goods and services are characterized by congestion. A famous article by Charles Tiebout in 1956 argued that voters reveal their preferences for local public goods and services through their choice of a community. Picking a community is like buying a shirt, he said, so if there are many communities, the outcome should be equally efficient.
25
Managerial Economics, Lecture 17: Public Goods The Tiebout Literature Subsequent analysis has revealed that having many local governments with different levels of service is more efficient than having a single local government. But a system with many local governments is perfectly efficient only under extreme assumptions, and policies to promote efficiency may still be needed. And this system is unlikely to be equitable.
26
Managerial Economics, Lecture 17: Public Goods The Tiebout Literature, 2 For example, local communities will be perfectly homogeneous only under extreme assumptions (such as completely flexible jurisdiction boundaries). But if communities are heterogeneous, the median voter may not pick the efficient level of local public services.
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.