Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published byAugust Logan Modified over 9 years ago
1
Chapter 3: DECISION ANALYSIS Part 2 1
2
Decision Making Under Risk Probabilistic decision situation States of nature have probabilities of occurrence. The probability estimate for the occurrence of each state of nature( if available) can be incorporated in the search for the optimal decision. For each decision calculate its expected payoff by 2 (Probability)(Payoff) Over States of Nature Expected Payoff =
3
Decision Making Under Risk (cont.) Select the decision with the best expected payoff 3
4
TOM BROWN - continued (0.2)(250) + (0.3)(200) + (0.3)(150) + (0.1)(-100) + (0.1)(-150) = 130 The Optimal decision 4
5
When to Use the Expected Value Approach The Expected Value Criterion is useful in cases where long run planning is appropriate, and decision situations repeat themselves. One problem with this criterion is that it does not consider attitude toward possible losses. Decision Making Criteria (cont.) 5
6
Expected Value of Perfect Information The gain in Expected Return obtained from knowing with certainty the future state of nature is called: Expected Value of Perfect Information (EVPI) It is also the Smallest Expect Regret of any decision alternative. Therefore, the EVPI is the expected regret corresponding to the decision selected using the expected value criterion 6
7
Expected Value of Perfect Information (cont.) EVPI = ERPI - EREV EREV: Expected Return of the EV criterion. Expected Return with Perfect Information ERPI= (best outcome of 1 st state of nature)*(Probability of 1 st state of nature) + ….. +(best outcome of last state of nature)*(Probability of last state of nature) 7
8
TOM BROWN - continued If it were known with certainty that there will be a “Large Rise” in the market Large rise... the optimal decision would be to invest in... -100 250 500 60 Stock Similarly, Expected Return with Perfect information = 0.2(500)+0.3(250)+0.3(200)+0.1(300)+0.1(60) = $271 EVPI = ERPI - EV = $271 - $130 = $141 8
9
Expected Value of Perfect Information (cont.) Another way to determine EVPI as follows If Tom knows the market will show a large rise, he should buy the “stock”, within profit $500, or a gain of $250 over what he would earn from the “bond” (optimal decision without the additional information). 9
10
Expected Value of Perfect Information (cont.) If Tom knows in advance the market would undergo His optimal decisionWith gain of payoff A large risestock500-250= $250 A small risestock250-200= $ 50 No changegold200-150= $ 50 A small fallgold300-(-100)=$400 A large fallC/D60-(-150)= 210 10 EVPI= 0.2(250) + 0.3(50) +0.3(50)+ 0.1(400)+ 0.1(210)= 141
11
Baysian Analysis - Decision Making with Imperfect Information Baysian Statistic play a role in assessing additional information obtained from various sources. This additional information may assist in refining original probability estimates, and help improve decision making. 11
12
TOM BROWN - continued Tom can purchase econometric forecast results for $50. The forecast predicts “negative” or “positive” econometric growth. Statistics regarding the forecast. When the stock market showed a large rise the forecast was “positive growth” 80% of the time. 12
13
TOM BROWN - continued P(forecast predicts “positive” | small rise in market) = 0.7 P(forecast predicts “ negative” | small rise in market) = 0.3 13 Should Tom purchase the Forecast ?
14
SOLUTION Tom should determine his optimal decisions when the forecast is “positive” and “negative”. If his decisions change because of the forecast, he should compare the expected payoff with and without the forecast. If the expected gain resulting from the decisions made with the forecast exceeds $50, he should purchase the forecast. 14
15
SOLUTION To find Expected payoff with forecast Tom should determine what to do when: The forecast is “positive growth” The forecast is “negative growth” 15
16
SOLUTION Tom needs to know the following probabilities P(Large rise | The forecast predicted “Positive”) P(Small rise | The forecast predicted “Positive”) P(No change | The forecast predicted “Positive ”) P(Small fall | The forecast predicted “Positive”) P(Large Fall | The forecast predicted “Positive”) 16
17
SOLUTION P(Large rise | The forecast predicted “Negative ”) P(Small rise | The forecast predicted “Negative”) P(No change | The forecast predicted “Negative”) P(Small fall | The forecast predicted “Negative”) P(Large Fall) | The forecast predicted “Negative”) 17 Bayes’ Theorem provides a procedure to calculate these probabilities
18
Bayes’ Theorem P(A|B) = Proof: p(A|B)= P (A and B) / P(B) (1) P(B|A)= P(A and B)/P(A) P(A and B) = P(B|A)*P(A) (1) P(A|B)=P(B|A)*P(A)/P(B) 18
19
Bayes’ Theorem (cont.) Often we begin probability analysis with initial or prior probabilities. Then, from a sample, special report, or product test we obtain some additional information. Given this information, we calculate revised or posterior probability. 19 Prior probabilities New information Posterior probabilities
20
Bayes’ Theorem(cont.) 20 P(B | A i )P(A i ) [ P(B | A 1 )P(A 1 )+ P(B | A 2 )P(A 2 )+…+ P(B | A n )P(A n ) ] P(A i | B) = Posterior probabilities Probabilities determined after the additional info becomes available Prior probabilities Probabilities estimated Determined based on Current info, before New info becomes available
21
The tabular approach to calculating posterior probabilities for positive economical forecast 21 X Ai: large rise B: forecast positive P(Bi |Ai )P(Ai) P(forecast= Positive| large rise)P( large rise)
22
22 X = The probability that the stock market shows “Large Rise” given that the forecast predicted “Positive” 0.16/ 0.56 Probability( forecast= positive) = 0.16+ 0.21+0.15+ 0.04+ 0.0 = 0.56 The Probability that the forecast is “positive” and the stock market shows “Large Rise”.
23
The tabular approach to calculating posterior probabilities for “negative” ecnomical forecast Probability (forecast= negative) = 0.44 23 X =
24
24 WINQSB printout for the calculation of the Posterior probabilities
25
25
26
26
27
27
28
28
29
29
30
30
31
31
32
32
33
33
34
34
35
35
36
gain from making decisions based on Sample Information. With the forecast available, the Expected Value of Return is revised. Calculate Revised Expected Values for a given forecast as follows. EV(Invest in……. | “Positive” forecast) = =.286( )+.375( )+.268( )+.071( )+0( ) = EV(Invest in ……. | “Negative” forecast) = =.091( )+.205( )+.341( )+.136( )+.227( ) = Gold -1001002003000 $84 -100 100 200 300 0 0 0 0 $120 Bond 250 200 150 -100 -150 $180 $ 65 36 Expected Value of Sample Information EVSI
37
The rest of the revised EV s are calculated in a similar manner. Invest in Stock when the Forecast is “Positive” Invest in Gold when the forecast is “Negative” ERSI = Expected Return with sample Information = (0.56)(250) + (0.44)(120) = $193 ERSI = Expected Return with sample Information = (0.56)(250) + (0.44)(120) = $193 EREV = Expected Value Without Sampling Information = 130 Expected Value of Sample Information - Excel So, Should Tom purchase the Forecast ? 37
38
EVSI = Expected Value of Sampling Information = ERSI - EREV = 193 - 130 = $63. Yes, Tom should purchase the Forecast. His expected return is greater than the Forecast cost. Efficiency = EVSI / EVPI = 63 / 141 = 0.45 38
39
Game Theory Game theory can be used to determine optimal decision in face of other decision making players. All the players are seeking to maximize their return. The payoff is based on the actions taken by all the decision making players. 39
40
Game Theory (cont.) Classification of Games Number of Players Two players - Chess Multiplayer - More than two competitors (Poker) Total return Zero Sum - The amount won and amount lost by all competitors are equal (Poker among friends) Nonzero Sum -The amount won and the amount lost by all competitors are not equal (Poker In A Casino) 40
41
Game Theory (cont.) Sequence of Moves Sequential - Each player gets a play in a given sequence. Simultaneous - All players play simultaneously. 41
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.