Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published byBernadette Barber Modified over 8 years ago
1
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 4 Utility
2
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 2 Preferences - A Reminder u x y: x is preferred strictly to y. x y: x and y are equally preferred. u x y: x is preferred at least as much as is y. ~
3
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 3 Preferences - A Reminder u Completeness: For any two bundles x and y it is always possible to state either that x y or that y x. ~ ~
4
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 4 Preferences - A Reminder u Reflexivity: Any bundle x is always at least as preferred as itself; i.e. x x. ~
5
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 5 Preferences - A Reminder u Transitivity: If x is at least as preferred as y, and y is at least as preferred as z, then x is at least as preferred as z; i.e. x y and y z x z. ~ ~ ~
6
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 6 Utility Functions u A preference relation that is complete, reflexive, transitive and continuous can be represented by a continuous utility function. u Continuity means that small changes to a consumption bundle cause only small changes to the preference level.
7
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 7 Utility Functions A utility function U(x) represents a preference relation if and only if: x’ x” U(x’) > U(x”) x’ x” U(x’) < U(x”) x’ x” U(x’) = U(x”). ~
8
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 8 Utility Functions u Utility is an ordinal (i.e. ordering) concept. u E.g. if U(x) = 6 and U(y) = 2 then bundle x is strictly preferred to bundle y. But x is not preferred three times as much as is y.
9
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 9 Utility Functions & Indiff. Curves u Consider the bundles (4,1), (2,3) and (2,2). Suppose (2,3) (4,1) (2,2). u Assign to these bundles any numbers that preserve the preference ordering; e.g. U(2,3) = 6 > U(4,1) = U(2,2) = 4. u Call these numbers utility levels.
10
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 10 Utility Functions & Indiff. Curves u An indifference curve contains equally preferred bundles. u Equal preference same utility level. u Therefore, all bundles in an indifference curve have the same utility level.
11
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 11 Utility Functions & Indiff. Curves So the bundles (4,1) and (2,2) are in the indiff. curve with utility level U But the bundle (2,3) is in the indiff. curve with utility level U 6. u On an indifference curve diagram, this preference information looks as follows:
12
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 12 Utility Functions & Indiff. Curves U 6 U 4 (2,3) (2,2) (4,1) x1x1 x2x2
13
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 13 Utility Functions & Indiff. Curves u Comparing more bundles will create a larger collection of all indifference curves and a better description of the consumer’s preferences.
14
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 14 Utility Functions & Indiff. Curves U 6 U 4 U 2 x1x1 x2x2
15
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 15 Utility Functions & Indiff. Curves u Comparing all possible consumption bundles gives the complete collection of the consumer’s indifference curves, each with its assigned utility level. u This complete collection of indifference curves completely represents the consumer’s preferences.
16
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 16 Utility Functions & Indiff. Curves x1x1 x2x2
17
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 17 Utility Functions & Indiff. Curves u The collection of all indifference curves for a given preference relation is an indifference map. u An indifference map is equivalent to a utility function; each is the other.
18
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 18 Utility Functions u There is no unique utility function representation of a preference relation. u Suppose U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 x 2 represents a preference relation. u Again consider the bundles (4,1), (2,3) and (2,2).
19
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 19 Utility Functions U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 x 2, so U(2,3) = 6 > U(4,1) = U(2,2) = 4; that is, (2,3) (4,1) (2,2).
20
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 20 Utility Functions U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 x 2 (2,3) (4,1) (2,2). u Define V = U 2.
21
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 21 Utility Functions U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 x 2 (2,3) (4,1) (2,2). u Define V = U 2. Then V(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 2 x 2 2 and V(2,3) = 36 > V(4,1) = V(2,2) = 16 so again (2,3) (4,1) (2,2). u V preserves the same order as U and so represents the same preferences.
22
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 22 Utility Functions U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 x 2 (2,3) (4,1) (2,2). u Define W = 2U + 10.
23
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 23 Utility Functions U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 x 2 (2,3) (4,1) (2,2). u Define W = 2U + 10. Then W(x 1,x 2 ) = 2x 1 x 2 +10 so W(2,3) = 22 > W(4,1) = W(2,2) = 18. Again, (2,3) (4,1) (2,2). u W preserves the same order as U and V and so represents the same preferences.
24
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 24 Utility Functions u If –U is a utility function that represents a preference relation and – f is a strictly increasing function, u then V = f(U) is also a utility function representing. ~ ~
25
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 25 Goods, Bads and Neutrals u A good is a commodity unit which increases utility (gives a more preferred bundle). u A bad is a commodity unit which decreases utility (gives a less preferred bundle). u A neutral is a commodity unit which does not change utility (gives an equally preferred bundle).
26
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 26 Goods, Bads and Neutrals Utility Water x’ Units of water are goods Units of water are bads Around x’ units, a little extra water is a neutral. Utility function
27
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 27 Some Other Utility Functions and Their Indifference Curves u Instead of U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 x 2 consider V(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 + x 2. What do the indifference curves for this “perfect substitution” utility function look like?
28
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 28 Perfect Substitution Indifference Curves 5 5 9 9 13 x1x1 x2x2 x 1 + x 2 = 5 x 1 + x 2 = 9 x 1 + x 2 = 13 V(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 + x 2.
29
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 29 Perfect Substitution Indifference Curves 5 5 9 9 13 x1x1 x2x2 x 1 + x 2 = 5 x 1 + x 2 = 9 x 1 + x 2 = 13 All are linear and parallel. V(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 + x 2.
30
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 30 Some Other Utility Functions and Their Indifference Curves u Instead of U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 x 2 or V(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 + x 2, consider W(x 1,x 2 ) = min{x 1,x 2 }. What do the indifference curves for this “perfect complementarity” utility function look like?
31
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 31 Perfect Complementarity Indifference Curves x2x2 x1x1 45 o min{x 1,x 2 } = 8 3 5 8 3 5 8 min{x 1,x 2 } = 5 min{x 1,x 2 } = 3 W(x 1,x 2 ) = min{x 1,x 2 }
32
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 32 Perfect Complementarity Indifference Curves x2x2 x1x1 45 o min{x 1,x 2 } = 8 3 5 8 3 5 8 min{x 1,x 2 } = 5 min{x 1,x 2 } = 3 All are right-angled with vertices on a ray from the origin. W(x 1,x 2 ) = min{x 1,x 2 }
33
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 33 Some Other Utility Functions and Their Indifference Curves u Any utility function of the form U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 a x 2 b with a > 0 and b > 0 is called a Cobb- Douglas utility function. u E.g. U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 1/2 x 2 1/2 (a = b = 1/2) V(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 x 2 3 (a = 1, b = 3)
34
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 34 Cobb-Douglas Indifference Curves x2x2 x1x1 All curves are hyperbolic, asymptoting to, but never touching any axis.
35
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 35 Marginal Utilities u Marginal means “incremental”. u The marginal utility of commodity i is the rate-of-change of total utility as the quantity of commodity i consumed changes; i.e.
36
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. Marginal Utilities u E.g. if U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 1/2 x 2 2 then
37
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. Marginal Utilities u E.g. if U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 1/2 x 2 2 then
38
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. Marginal Utilities u E.g. if U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 1/2 x 2 2 then
39
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. Marginal Utilities u E.g. if U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 1/2 x 2 2 then
40
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. Marginal Utilities u So, if U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 1/2 x 2 2 then
41
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 41 Marginal Utilities and Marginal Rates-of-Substitution The general equation for an indifference curve is U(x 1,x 2 ) k, a constant. Totally differentiating this identity gives
42
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 42 Marginal Utilities and Marginal Rates-of-Substitution rearranged is
43
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 43 Marginal Utilities and Marginal Rates-of-Substitution rearranged is And This is the MRS.
44
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 44 Marg. Utilities & Marg. Rates-of- Substitution; An example u Suppose U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 x 2. Then so
45
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 45 Marg. Utilities & Marg. Rates-of- Substitution; An example MRS(1,8) = - 8/1 = -8 MRS(6,6) = - 6/6 = -1. x1x1 x2x2 8 6 16 U = 8 U = 36 U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 x 2 ;
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.