Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published byNatalie Hodge Modified over 8 years ago
1
Social Balance & Hierarchy Overview Background: Basic Balance Theory Extensions to directed graphs Triads Theoretical Implications: Micro foundations of macro structure Implications for networks dynamics
2
How do we capture hierarchy in a network? The shape of the popularity distribution is essentially constant over time and across each state/cohort combination. Males differ from females in having greater numbers of people receiving zero nominations. In all cases (and within each network), we get a fairly skewed distribution of popularity, reflecting a small number of very popular students.
3
Popularity Structure: Macro level stability The shape of the popularity distribution is essentially constant over time and across each state/cohort combination. Males differ from females in having greater numbers of people receiving zero nominations. In all cases (and within each network), we get a fairly skewed distribution of popularity, reflecting a small number of very popular students.
4
The Skewness coefficient captures the length of the tail of the popularity distribution, and is essentially constant across networks of more than ~100 students. Popularity Structure: Macro level stability
5
Distribution of Popularity By size and city type Popularity Structure: Macro level stability Add Health comparison
6
Social Balance & Transitivity Heider’s work on cognition of social situations, which can be boiled down to the relations among three ‘actors’: PO X Person Other Object Heider was interested in the correspondence of P and O, given their beliefs about X
7
+ - Like: Dislike Two Relations: Social Balance & Transitivity Each dyad (PO, PX, OX) can take on one of two values: + or - 8 POX triples: + + + p o x - - + p o x - + - p o x + - - p o x + + - p o x - + + p o x + - + p o x - - - p o x
8
Social Balance & Transitivity The 8 triples can be reduced if we ignore the distinction between POX: + + + p o x - - + p o x - + - p o x + - - p o x + + - p o x - + + p o x + - + p o x - - - p o x + + + - - + + + - - - -
9
Social Balance & Transitivity We determine balance based on the product of the edges: + + + - - + + + - - - - (+)(+)(+) = (+) (-)(+)(-) = (-) (-)(-)(-) = (-) (+)(-)(+) = (-) Balanced Unbalanced “A friend of a friend is a friend” “An enemy of my enemy is a friend” “An enemy of my enemy is an enemy” “A Friend of a Friend is an enemy”
10
Social Balance & Transitivity Heider argued that unbalanced triads would be unstable: They should transform toward balance + + - + + + - + - + - - Become Friends Become Enemies
11
Social Balance & Transitivity IF such a balancing process were active throughout the graph, all intransitive triads would be eliminated from the network. This would result in one of two possible graphs (Balance Theorem): Friends with Enemies with Balanced Opposition Complete Clique
12
Social Balance & Hierarchy Empirically, we often find that graphs break up into more than two groups. What does this imply for balance theory? It turns out, that if you allow all negative triads, you can get a graph with many clusters. That is, instead of treating (-)(-)(-) as an forbidden triad, treat it as allowed. This implies that the micro rule is different: negative ties among enemies are not as motivating as positive ties.
13
Social Balance & Transitivity Empirically, we also rarely have symmetric relations (at least on affect) thus we need to identify balance in undirected relations. Directed dyads can be in one of three states: 1) Mutual 2) Asymmetric 3) Null Every triad is composed of 3 dyads, and we can identify triads based on the number of each type, called the MAN label system
14
Social Balance & Transitivity Balance in directed relations Actors seek out transitive relations, and avoid intransitive relations. A triple is transitive A property of triples within triads Assumes directed relations The saliency of a triad may differ for each actor, depending on their position within the triad. ij & jk ik If: then:
15
120C a b c Ordered Triples: abc; Transitive ac acb; Vacuous ab b a c;bc bca; Intransitive ba c ab; Intransitive cb cba; Vacuous ca Social Balance & Transitivity Once we admit directed relations, we need to decompose triads into their constituent triples.
16
Network Sub-Structure: Triads 003 (0) 012 (1) 102 021D 021U 021C (2) 111D 111U 030T 030C (3) 201 120D 120U 120C (4) 210 (5) 300 (6) Intransitive Transitive Mixed
17
An Example of the triad census Type Number of triads --------------------------------------- 1 - 003 21 --------------------------------------- 2 - 012 26 3 - 102 11 4 - 021D 1 5 - 021U 5 6 - 021C 3 7 - 111D 2 8 - 111U 5 9 - 030T 3 10 - 030C 1 11 - 201 1 12 - 120D 1 13 - 120U 1 14 - 120C 1 15 - 210 1 16 - 300 1 --------------------------------------- Sum (2 - 16): 63
18
Social Balance & Transitivity As with undirected graphs, you can use the type of triads allowed to characterize the total graph. But now the potential patterns are much more diverse 1) All triads are 030T: A perfect linear hierarchy.
19
Social Balance & Transitivity Triads allowed: {300, 102} M M N* 1 1 0 0
20
Social Balance & Transitivity Cluster Structure, allows triads: {003, 300, 102} M M N* M M Eugene Johnsen (1985, 1986) specifies a number of structures that result from various triad configurations 1 1 1 1
21
P RC {300,102, 003, 120D, 120U, 030T, 021D, 021U} Ranked Cluster: M M N* M M M A* Social Balance & Transitivity 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 10 0 0 0000 00 00 And many more...
22
Social Balance & Transitivity Substantively, specifying a set of triads defines a behavioral mechanism, and we can use the distribution of triads in a network to test whether the hypothesized mechanism is active. We do this by (1) counting the number of each triad type in a given network and (2) comparing it to the expected number, given some random distribution of ties in the network. See Wasserman and Faust, Chapter 14 for computation details, and the SPAN manual for SAS code that will generate these distributions, if you so choose.
23
Social Balance & Transitivity Triad: 003 012 102 021D 021U 021C 111D 111U 030T 030C 201 120D 120U 120C 210 300 BA Triad Micro-Models: BA: Ballance (Cartwright and Harary, ‘56) CL: Clustering Model (Davis. ‘67) RC: Ranked Cluster (Davis & Leinhardt, ‘72) R2C: Ranked 2-Clusters (Johnsen, ‘85) TR: Transitivity (Davis and Leinhardt, ‘71) HC: Hierarchical Cliques (Johnsen, ‘85) 39+: Model that fits D&L’s 742 mats N :39-72 p1-p4: Johnsen, 1986. Process Agreement Models. CLRCR2CTRHC39+p1p2p3p4
24
Social Balance & Transitivity Structural Indices based on the distribution of triads The observed distribution of triads can be fit to the hypothesized structures using weighting vectors for each type of triad. Where: l = 16 element weighting vector for the triad types T = the observed triad census T = the expected value of T T = the variance-covariance matrix for T
25
-100 0 100 200 300 400 t-value Triad Census Distributions Standardized Difference from Expected Data from Add Health 012 102 021D 021U 021C 111D 111U 030T 030C 201 120D 120U 120C 210300
26
Social Balance & Transitivity For the Add Health data, the observed distribution of the tau statistic for various models was: Indicating that a ranked-cluster model fits the best.
27
Popularity Structure: Macro level stability
28
Testing Theories of Friendship -0.6 -0.4 -0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 Same Race SES GPA Both Smoke College Drinking Fight Reciprocity Same Sex Same Clubs Transitivity Intransitivity Same Grade Standardized Coefficients from an Exponential Random Graph Model
29
Social Balance & Transitivity So far, we’ve focused on the graph ‘at equilibrium.’ That is, we have hypothesized structures once people have made all the choices they are going to make. What we have not done, is really look closely at the implication of changing relations. That is, we might say that triad 030C should not occur, but what would a change in this triad imply from the standpoint of the actor making a relational change?
30
Social Balance & Transitivity
32
Random Walk Social Balance & Transitivity
33
Transitive =.5, Intran & Pos = 0. Social Balance & Transitivity
34
Trans=1.0 Social Balance & Transitivity
35
Strong Negative (INT=-2) Social Balance & Transitivity
36
003 102 021D 030T 201 120U 120C 210 300 012 021C 021U 111D 111U 030C 120D Social Balance & Transitivity Observed triad transition patterns, from Hallinan’s data.
37
Transitivity Density Social Balance & Transitivity Strong Transitivity Simulation
38
Social Balance & Transitivity Strong Intransitivity Simulation
39
Social Balance & Transitivity Strong Intransitivity Simulation Ideal-typical results
40
Social Balance & Transitivity Moderate values on both Simulation
41
Social Balance & Transitivity
43
Newcomb, PI layout A Brief History of Balance Through Time
44
Social Balance & Transitivity Newcomb, PI layout A Brief History of Balance Through Time
45
Social Balance & Transitivity A Brief History of Balance Through Time
46
PNAS
47
Homophily as social balance: Variable attributes
48
Homophily as social balance: Fixed attributes
49
Micro mobility within settings Here we see (normalized) mobility tables, looking at movement between quintiles of the popularity distribution. While most movement is short- distances, there is a good deal of movement in overall status. Only half of the most/least popular kids remain so a year later, dropping to between 30 and 40 across wider time- spans. Tables on popularity quintiles, correlations on percentile-rank between each wave.
50
Micro mobility within settings Here we see (normalized) mobility tables, looking at movement between quintiles of the popularity distribution. While most movement is short- distances, there is a good deal of movement in overall status. Only half of the most/least popular kids remain so a year later, dropping to between 30 and 40 across wider time- spans. Tables on popularity quintiles, correlations on percentile-rank between each wave.
51
Micro mobility within settings An individual-based perspective: chances of being in the top quintile x times given time in the bottom quintile. For example only 3.9% of kids are in the most popular quintile all 5 waves, and a full 50% are in the top quintile at least once over the observation period. Similarly, only 1.9% of kids are least popular all 5 waves, but 43% are least popular at least once.
52
Micro mobility within settings Another view: Tracking trajectories over time. Here we have a random sample of 15 kids’ trajectories, with increasing popularity in red, decreasing in blue. Note the many different patterns…
53
Jefferson Sunshine An individual’s position in the status hierarchy is also not stable: Micro mobility within settings (Add Health)
54
Capturing Trajectories Tracking Trajectories: How do we characterize a popularity trajectory? - Cluster analysis: - Goal is to find similar patterns across the set of 5-wave trajectories. - Advantage: you have great flexibility in the actual pattern - Disadvantages: - Exploratory & can capitalize on randomness - Time/Data intensive - Need to decide on numbers-of-clusters -In the end this was not convincing: no clear separation in the clusters nor interpretable clustering tree. -Instead, what jumps out is the sheer variability in experiences across cases.
55
Capturing Trajectories Tracking Trajectories: Smooth “field of experiences” approach: - Fit a simple linear model to change over time for each student.: the combination of intercept and slope then describe the *general* trajectory of popularity each student experiences…. …but, the trend removes all the variability in movement around the trend; which is likely important for one’s experience in the setting: we want to distinguish a steady trajectory from a wildly swinging one. So we add an additional indicator of the standard deviation of popularity to the model. Combined, these two features (regression parameters & variance) capture the direction and “width” of trajectory experiences.
56
The regression estimates define a simple 2-d space of slope (Y) and intercept (x). This figure represents the distribution of cases across that space, with key points labeled. Capturing Trajectories
57
The regression estimates define a simple 2-d space of slope (Y) and intercept (x). This region represents steady & sharp increases in popularity, from a low starting point to a high ending point. These kids are upwardly mobile Capturing Trajectories
58
The regression estimates define a simple 2-d space of slope (Y) and intercept (x). In contrast, here we have steady but sharp decline – these kids are downwardly mobile. Capturing Trajectories
59
The regression estimates define a simple 2-d space of slope (Y) and intercept (x). …and three “steady” states: kids with stable popularity. Note there is no clumping in the space, but a true continuous field, and also note that variability is correlated with slope, so we need to disentangle that in the models. Capturing Trajectories
60
Examples of Hierarchical Systems Linear Hierarchy (all triads transitive) Simple Hierarchy Branched Hierarchy Mixed Hierarchy
61
Examples of “Similar” Non-Hierarchical Systems Acyclic Cycle Line Graph
62
Chase’s Question: Where does hierarchy come from? Hierarchy surrounds us, in natural (animal and human) and controlled (laboratory, organizations) settings. How do we account for it? Most previous research focuses on the static structure of hierarchy Often consider the attributes of actors: strength, race, gender, education, size, etc.
63
Chase’s Question: Where does hierarchy come from? The “Correlational Model” Individual’s position in the hierarchy is due to their attributes (physical, social, etc.) Mathematically, for the correlational model to be true, the correspondence between attributes and rank in the hierarchy would have to be extremely high (Pearson correlation of >.9). (See Chase, 1974 for details)
64
Chase’s Question: Where does hierarchy come from? The “Pairwise interaction” model Pairwise differences in each dyad account for position in the hierarchy. “...it is assumed that each member of a group has a pairwise contest with each other member, that the winner of a contest dominates the loser in the group hierarchy, and that an individual has a particular probability of success in each contest.” Model implies that there be one individual with a.95 probability of beating every other individual, another with a.95 probability of beating everyone but the most dominant, and so forth down the line. The required conditions simply do not hold. As such, this explanation for where the hierarchy comes from cannot hold.
65
Chase’s Question: Where does hierarchy come from? Chase focuses on the simple mathematical fact: Every linear hierarchy must contain all transitive triads. That is, the triad census for the network must have only 030T triads. A B C D E Number of Type triads ---------------------- 1 - 003 0 ----------------------- 2 - 012 0 3 - 102 0 4 - 021D 0 5 - 021U 0 6 - 021C 0 7 - 111D 0 8 - 111U 0 9 - 030T 10 10 - 030C 0 11 - 201 0 12 - 120D 0 13 - 120U 0 14 - 120C 0 15 - 210 0 16 - 300 0 --------------------------- Sum (2 - 16): 10 What process could generate all 030T triads?
66
Chase’s Question: Where does hierarchy come from? A CB Transitive (030T) triad A CB Intransitive (030C) triad The elements: Dominance relations must by asymmetric, thus, the set of possible triads is limited.
67
Why Chase Finds Linear Hierarchy: 003 012 021D 021U 021C 030C 030T p=1. p=.5 p=.25 p=.5 p=1 p=.5 P( 3 C) =.5*.5=.25 P(030T)= (.5*.5 +.25*1 +.25*1) =.75 Triad transitions (w/ Random Expectations) for Dominance Relations.
68
Dominance Strategies That ensure a transitive hierarchy 003 012 021D 030T The “Double Attack” Strategy: The first attacker quickly attacks the bystander. This means we arrive at 21D, and any action on the part of the other two chickens will lead to a transitive triad. The “Double Receive” Strategy: The first attacker dominates B, and then the bystander quickly dominates B as well, leading to 21U, and any dominance between the first and second attacker will lead to a transitive triple. 003 012 021U 030T
69
Dominance Strategies That may not lead to a transitive hierarchy “Attack the Attacker” The bystander attacks the first attacker. This could lead to a cyclic triad, and thus thwart hierarchy. 003 012 021C 030C 030T “Pass on the attack” The one who is attacked, attacks the bystander. Again, this could lead to a cycle, and thus thwart hierarchy. 003 012 021C 030C 030T
70
The evidence : 24 Chase Chicken Triads 003 012 021D 021U 021C 030C 030 T 23 17 1 (17 stay) 4 4 2 1 1 1 Domination Reversal New Domination (1 stays) (6 Fully Transitive) ( 0 stay) Most Common Path
71
The Origins of Status Hierarchies: A formal model and empirical test Hierarchy & Inequality appear virtually universal. How do we account for it? Two alternative explanations: Individualist – that people vary in qualities that are locally salient Structuralist – that differentiation results from the quality of social positions individuals occupy. Third option: Hierarchy is explained as the product of an emergent social process without presupposing that the resulting assignment of actors to positions is a reflection of underlying qualities. The key is that: “social hierarchies are understood to emerge and persists spontaneously rather than by conscious creation, but at the same time without ensuring that rewards exactly reflect differences in individual qualities” (p.1146)
72
The Origins of Status Hierarchies: A formal model and empirical test Theoretical claim: “the reason positions with greater and lesser advantage exist is that judgments about relative quality are socially influenced. Socially influenced judgments amplify underlying differences, so that actors who objectively rank above the mean on some abstract quality dimension are overvalued with those ranking below the mean are undervalued….Amplification occurs because observable interactions expressing judgments of quality are also cues to other actors seeking guidance for their own judgments.” (p.1147) Examples include the “Mathew effect” in science
73
This claim is theoretically consistent with a Nash Equilibrium, in which everyone’s current choice of action is preferable to (or as good as) the alternatives so long as everyone else’s choice of action remains constant. IF attribution builds on others’ attributions, then, “the patterns should tend toward a stable state in which collective attributions confirm themselves in each time period.” The theory implies that “the only equilibria possible when there are absolutely no underlying differences across individuals are one in which everyone is ranked equally and one in which one actor receives attention while all others receive none.” (p.1149) This follows because of the ‘cascade’ effect of social influence. The Origins of Status Hierarchies: A formal model and empirical test
74
Since most observed structures fall between these two poles, something else must be going on as well. The mechanism employed rests on the returns to asymmetric admiration. “It is painful to pay attention to another person if the favor is not repaid. By the same token, it is particularly pleasant to receive attention when it is not solicited.” “Individuals should be less willing to demonstrate esteem toward those who do not return the favor and conversely may prefer to receive such demonstrations without reciprocating.” The Origins of Status Hierarchies: A formal model and empirical test
75
The theory then makes three predictions: 1)Asymmetry in social relationships will be proportional to the difference in choice status (indegree) between pairs of actors. A high-status actor will be more weakly connected to any low-status actor that the latter is to her or him. This has to exceed the chance/tautology levels. 2)All else equal, pairs of actors who are similar in choice status will also be similar in the patterns of attachments they make to others. 3)Across all actors, the sum of attachments directed to others will be proportional to, but more evenly distributed than, the sum of attachments received. The Origins of Status Hierarchies: A formal model and empirical test
76
Formally, the model: 1)Assumes a closed, finite population 2)The quantity of attachments varies across individuals 3)Each actor cares about: a)The quality of each potential alter b)The gap between their and the alter’s attachment to each other. Ui = utility for person i a ij = attachment of person i to person j q j = quality of person j S = a weight of symmetry considerations relative to the quality of i’s alters in determining i’s welfare. In this model, q is determined exogenously
77
The Origins of Status Hierarchies: A formal model and empirical test To extend the model for social influence, assume that quality judgments are a function of peer influence: q ij = i’s assessment of j’s quality Q j = exogenous quality of j W = relative weight of social influence on I’s judgment of j.
78
The Origins of Status Hierarchies: A formal model and empirical test Prediction from equation 6 (aggregate quality centered at 0)
79
The Origins of Status Hierarchies: A formal model and empirical test (Close-up of threshold region)
80
The Origins of Status Hierarchies: A formal model and empirical test Analysis of the model results is a set of testable propositions: 1)Asymmetry in attachments between any two actors is proportional to their differences in choice status 2)The relationship between choice status and asymmetry declines with group size 3)Any pair of actors i,j will be similar in the attachments they direct toward others in proportion as they are similar in choice status. 4)If sum(choice kj) – sum(choice ki) = 0, then aik – aij = 0. 5)Actors direct attachments to others in proportion to the quantity of attachments received 6)The slope of the function that transforms choice status into attachments directed outward is always less than unity. Consequently, the distribution of choice status (popularity) is more unequal than the distribution of out degree.
81
The Origins of Status Hierarchies: A formal model and empirical test.80
82
The Origins of Status Hierarchies: A formal model and empirical test
83
So the model seems to be well supported by the data. -I’ve played a little with these models and Add Health, and they don’t perform as well, but the data don’t fit the assumptions either….
84
Graph Theoretic Dimensions of Informal Organizations What can SNA tell us about dominance in organizations? Krackhardt argues that an ‘Outree” is the archetype of hierarchy. (what are the allowed triad types for an out-tree?) Krackhardt focuses on 4 dimensions: 1) Connectedness 2) Digraph hierarchic 3) digraph efficiency 4) least upper bound
85
Graph Theoretic Dimensions of Informal Organizations Connectedness: The digraph is connected if the underlying graph is a component. We can measure the extent of connectedness through reachability. Where V is the number of pairs that are not reachable, and N is the number of people in the network.
86
Graph Theoretic Dimensions of Informal Organizations How to calculate Connectedness: 1 2 3 5 4 Digraph: 1 2 3 4 5 1 0 1 0 1 0 2 0 0 1 0 0 3 0 0 0 0 0 4 0 0 0 0 0 5 0 0 0 0 0 Graph: 1 2 3 4 5 1 0 1 0 1 0 2 1 0 1 0 0 3 0 1 0 0 0 4 1 0 0 0 0 5 0 0 0 0 0 Reach: 1 2 3 4 5 1 0 1 2 1 0 2 1 0 1 2 0 3 2 1 0 3 0 4 1 2 3 0 0 5 0 0 0 0 0 V = # of zeros in the upper diagonal of Reach: V = 4. C = 1 - [4/((5*4)/2)] = 1 - 4/1 =.6
87
Graph Theoretic Dimensions of Informal Organizations How to calculate Connectedness: 1 2 3 5 4 This is equivalent to the density of the reachability matrix. Reachable: 1 2 3 4 5 1 0 1 1 1 0 2 1 0 1 1 0 3 1 1 0 1 0 4 1 1 1 0 0 5 0 0 0 0 0 = R/(N(N-1)) = 12 /(5*4) =.6 Reach: 1 2 3 4 5 1 0 1 2 1 0 2 1 0 1 2 0 3 2 1 0 3 0 4 1 2 3 0 0 5 0 0 0 0 0
88
Graph Theoretic Dimensions of Informal Organizations Graph Hierarchy: The extent to which people are asymmetrically reachable. Where V is the number of symmetrically reachable pairs in the network. Max(V) is the number of pairs where i can reach j or j can reach i.
89
Graph Theoretic Dimensions of Informal Organizations 1 2 3 5 4 Graph Hierarchy: An example Digraph: 1 2 3 4 5 1 0 1 0 1 0 2 0 0 1 0 0 3 0 1 0 0 0 4 0 0 0 0 0 5 0 0 0 0 0 Dreach 1 2 3 4 5 1 0 1 2 1 0 2 0 0 1 0 0 3 0 1 0 0 0 4 0 0 0 0 0 5 0 0 0 0 0 V = 1 Max(V) = 4 H = 1/4 =.25 Dreachable 1 2 3 4 5 1 0 1 2 1 0 2 0 0 1 0 0 3 0 1 0 0 0 4 0 0 0 0 0 5 0 0 0 0 0
90
Graph Theoretic Dimensions of Informal Organizations Graph Efficiency: The extent to which there are extra lines in the graph, given the number of components. Where v is the number of excess links and max(v) is the maximum possible number of excess links
91
1 2 3 5 4 6 7 Graph Theoretic Dimensions of Informal Organizations Graph Efficiency: The minimum number of lines in a connected component is N-1 (assuming symmetry, only use the upper half of the adjacency matrix). In this example, the first component contains 4 nodes and thus the minimum required lines is 3. There are 4 lines, and thus V1= 4-3 = 1. The second component contains 3 nodes and thus minimum connectivity is = 2, there are 3 so V2 = 1. Summed over all components V=2. The maximum number of lines would occur if every node was connected to every other, and equals N(N-1)/2. For the first component Max(V1) = (6-3)=3. For the second, Max(V2) = (3-2)=1, so Max(V) = 4. Efficiency = (1- 2/4 ) =.5 1 2
92
Graph Theoretic Dimensions of Informal Organizations Graph Efficiency: Steps to calculate efficiency: a) identify all components in the graph b) for each component (i) do: i) calculate Vi = (Gi)/2 - Ni-1; ii) calculate Max(Vi) = Ni(Ni-1) - (Ni-1) c) V = (Vi), Max(V)= (Max(Vi) d) efficiency = 1 - V/Max(V) Substantively, this must be a function of the average density of the components in the graph.
93
Graph Theoretic Dimensions of Informal Organizations Least Upper Boundedness: This condition looks at how many ‘roots’ there are in the tree. The LUB for any pair of actors is the closest person who can reach both of them. In a formal hierarchy, every pair should have at least one LUB. A D B C E In this case, E is the LUB for (A,D), B is the LUB for (F,G), H is the LUB for (D,C), etc. F G H
94
Graph Theoretic Dimensions of Informal Organizations Least Upper Boundedness: You get a violation of LUB if two people in the organization do not have an (eventual) common boss. Here, persons 4 and 7 do not have an LUB.
95
Graph Theoretic Dimensions of Informal Organizations Least Upper Boundedness: Calculate LUB by looking at reachability. Distance matrix 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 1 1 1 2 2 2 2 1 1 1 3 1 1 4 1 5 1 6 1 1 1 2 7 1 1 8 1 9 1 (Note that I set the diagonal = 1) Reachable matrix 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 1 1 1 3 1 1 4 1 5 1 6 1 1 1 1 7 1 1 8 1 9 1 A violation occurs whenever a pair is not reachable by at least one common node. We can get common reachability through matrix multiplication
96
Graph Theoretic Dimensions of Informal Organizations Least Upper Boundedness: Calculate LUB by looking at reachability. Reachable matrix 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 1 1 1 3 1 1 4 1 5 1 6 1 1 1 1 7 1 1 8 1 9 1 R`*R = CR Reachable Trans 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 2 1 1 3 1 1 4 1 1 1 5 1 1 1 6 1 7 1 1 8 1 1 9 1 1 1 1 1 X = Common Reach 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 0 0 1 2 1 2 1 2 2 0 0 0 1 3 1 1 2 1 1 0 0 0 2 4 1 2 1 3 2 0 0 0 1 5 1 2 1 2 3 0 0 0 1 6 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 1 7 0 0 0 0 0 1 2 1 2 8 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 2 1 9 1 1 2 1 1 1 2 1 5 Any place with a zero indicates a pair that does not have a LUB. (R by S)(S by R) (R by R)
97
Graph Theoretic Dimensions of Informal Organizations Least Upper Boundedness: Calculate LUB by looking at reachability. Where V = number of pairs that have no LUB, summed over all components, and:
98
Other characteristics of Hierarchy: DAG: Directed, Acyclic, Graph Graph that: contains no cycles at least one node has in-degree Rank Cluster Graph in which some number of nodes are mutually reachable, but asymmetrically reachable between groups. Tree A DAG with only one root Centralization
99
Another method: Approximation based on permutation One characteristic of a hierarchy is that most of the ties fall on the upper triangle of the adjacency matrix. Thus, one way to get an order is by juggling the rows and columns until most of the ties are in the upper triangle. 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 1 1 2 1 3 4 1 1 5 1 6 1 1 7 8 1 1 1 9 1 1 1 1 1 11 1 12 1 1 13 1 1 1 14 1 1 1 15 16 17 1 18 1
100
Another method: Approximation based on permutation 13 1 1 1 14 1 1 1 9 1 1 1 1 1 2 1 11 1 5 1 1 8 1 1 1 18 1 17 1 4 1 1 6 1 1 12 1 1 3 7 15 16 Re-ordered matrix
101
Group Hierarchy McFarland et al (2014) We wanted to examine hierarchy variability across all the add health schools. We have a continuous measure based on the triad distribution, but also created this as a way to illustrate: a)Blockmodel the network to identify positions. b)Use Becker’s algorithm to sort positing mixing matrix in hierarchical order. c)Network level hierarchy is ratio of ties above diagonal to ties below d)Position level hierarchy (y-axis) is ratio of ties received to ties sent e)For clarity, only ploted ties that are at least 75% of the mean value Hierarchy here is the coefficient from the GWESP term in our models
102
Group Hierarchy McFarland et al (2014) We wanted to examine hierarchy variability across all the add health schools. We have a continuous measure based on the triad distribution, but also created this as a way to illustrate: a)Blockmodel the network to identify positions. b)Use Becker’s algorithm to sort positing mixing matrix in hierarchical order. c)Network level hierarchy is ratio of ties above diagonal to ties below d)Position level hierarchy (y-axis) is ratio of ties received to ties sent e)For clarity, only ploted ties that are at least 75% of the mean value
103
Martin: Social Structures Martin’s project is directly related to the early balance models: Can we find necessary/likely/expected structures created by the constraints forced by the type of tie. Mutual (aRb bRa, aRa, (aRb & bRc, aRc) Equality Archetype is the clique Asymmetric (aRb has no implication for bRa) Archetype is the gift/donation Question’s the emergence of equality & stability given tendencies toward “Matthew effects” Anti-symmetric (aRb not(bRa), transitivity) Pecking Orders & Patronage
104
Martin: Social Structures Mutual (aRb bRa, aRa, (aRb & bRc, aRc) Equality Archetype is the clique Problem is that the structure collapses under its own weight, since we can’t have clusters of N*N-1 people. So we differentiate: By types of tie/person:
105
Martin: Social Structures Mutual (aRb bRa, aRa, (aRb & bRc, aRc) Equality Archetype is the clique Problem is that the structure collapses under its own weight, since we can’t have clusters of N*N-1 people. So we differentiate: Social distance OR geographic distance
106
Martin: Social Structures Mutual (aRb bRa, aRa, (aRb & bRc, aRc) Equality Archetype is the clique Problem is that the structure collapses under its own weight, since we can’t have clusters of N*N-1 people. So we differentiate (creating weighted ties): Then he moves on to discuss alternative social rules to balance, which never quite works leading to claims about rules across equivalents (which we will cover later)
107
Martin: Social Structures Mutual (aRb bRa, aRa, (aRb & bRc, aRc) Equality Archetype is the clique A social constraint space for network structure
108
Martin: Social Structures How do we make sense of our options? individual models (p1) or generalized exchange (later) Asymmetric (aRb has no implication for bRa)
109
Martin: Social Structures Anti-symmetric (aRb not(bRa), transitivity) Pecking Orders & Patronage
110
Martin: Social Structures Anti-symmetric (aRb not(bRa), transitivity) Pecking Orders & Patronage
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.