Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published byGriselda Gibson Modified over 8 years ago
1
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2010 Lecture 10
2
1 Midterm on Wednesday Office hours tomorrow (Soc Sci 7428) 1:30-3:30 p.m. Logistics
3
2 Finished property law Began to motivate contract law Why do we need contracts? To get cooperation/trade when transactions aren’t instantaneous Examples: buying a plane ticket; painting someone’s house; investment opportunity Last week…
4
3 Example: I have an investment opportunity, you have money You Trust meDon’t Me Keep the moneyShare the money (-100, 200)(50, 50) (0, 0) You Trust meDon’t Me Keep the moneyShare the money (25, 25)(50, 50) (0, 0) Without binding contracts With enforceable contracts
5
4 “The rich uncle of a struggling college student learns at the graduation party that his nephew graduated with honors. Swept away by good feeling, the uncle promises the nephew a trip around the world. Later the uncle reneges on his promise. The student sues his uncle, asking the court to compel the uncle to pay for a trip around the world.” “One neighbor offers to sell a used car to another for $1000. The buyer gives the money to the seller, and the seller gives the car keys to the buyer. To her great surprise, the buyer discovers that the keys fit the rusting Chevrolet in the back yard, not the shiny Cadillac in the driveway. The seller is equally surprised to learn that the buyer expected the Cadillac. The buyer asks the court to order the seller to turn over the Cadillac.” “A farmer, in response to a magazine ad for “a sure means to kill grasshoppers,” mails $25 and receives in the mail two wooden blocks with the instructions, “Place grasshopper on Block A and smash with Block B.” The buyer asks the court to require the seller to return the $25 and pay $500 in punitive damages.” So… what types of promises should be enforced by the law?
6
5 The Bargain Theory of Contracts
7
6 Developed in the late 1800s/early 1900s A promise should be enforced if it was given as part of a bargain, otherwise it should not Bargains were taken to have three elements Offer Acceptance Consideration The bargain theory of contracts
8
7 Promisor: person who gives a promise Promisee: person who receives it In a bargain, both sides must give up something reciprocal inducement Consideration is what the promisee gives to the promisor, in exchange for the promise Under the bargain theory, a contract becomes enforceable once consideration is given What is consideration?
9
8 Promisor: person who gives a promise Promisee: person who receives it In a bargain, both sides must give up something reciprocal inducement Consideration is what the promisee gives to the promisor, in exchange for the promise Under the bargain theory, a contract becomes enforceable once consideration is given What is consideration?
10
9 Hamer v Sidway (NY Appeals Ct, 1891) Uncle offered nephew $5,000 to give up drinking and smoking until his 21 st birthday, then refused to pay “The promisee [previously] used tobacco, occasionally drank liquor, and he had a legal right to do so. That right he abandoned for a period of years upon the strength of the promise… We need not speculate on the effort which may have been required to give up the use of these stimulants. It is sufficient that he restricted his lawful freedom of action within certain prescribed limits upon the faith of his uncle’s agreement, and now, having fully performed the conditions imposed, it is of no moment whether such performance actually proved a benefit to the promisor, and the court will not inquire into it.” The bargain theory does not distinguish between fair and unfair bargains
11
10 Expectation damages the amount of benefit the promisee could reasonably expect from performance of the promise meant to make the promisee as well of as he would have been, had the promise been fulfilled Under the bargain theory, what is the remedy?
12
11 Problems with the bargain theory Not that accurate a description of what modern courts actually do Not always efficient Does not enforce certain promises that both promisor and promisee might have wanted to be enforceable
13
12 Problems with the bargain theory Not that accurate a description of what modern courts actually do Not always efficient Does not enforce certain promises that both promisor and promisee might have wanted to be enforceable Does enforce certain promises that maybe should not be enforced
14
13 What does efficiency say about what promises should be enforced?
15
14 What promises should be enforced? In general, efficiency requires enforcing a promise if both the promisor and the promisee wanted it to be enforceable when it was made different from wanting it to actually be enforced
16
15 What promises should be enforced? In general, efficiency requires enforcing a promise if both the promisor and the promisee wanted it to be enforceable when it was made different from wanting it to actually be enforced The first purpose of contract law is to enable people to cooperate by converting games with noncooperative solutions into games with cooperative solutions or, enable people to convert games with inefficient equilibria into games with efficient equilibria
17
16 What promises should be enforced? In general, efficiency requires enforcing a promise if both the promisor and the promisee wanted it to be enforceable when it was made different from wanting it to actually be enforced The first purpose of contract law is to enable people to cooperate by converting games with noncooperative solutions into games with cooperative solutions or, enable people to convert games with inefficient equilibria into games with efficient equilibria
18
17 So now we know… What promises should be enforceable? For efficiency: enforce those which both promisor and promisee wanted to be enforceable when they were made One purpose of contract law Enable cooperation by changing a game to have a cooperative solution Contract law can serve a number of other purposes as well
19
18 Information Private/asymmetric information can hinder trade Car example (George Akerloff, “The Market for Lemons”)
20
19 Information Private/asymmetric information can hinder trade Car example (George Akerloff, “The Market for Lemons”)
21
20 Information Private/asymmetric information can hinder trade Car example (George Akerloff, “The Market for Lemons”) Contract law could help You could offer me a legally binding warranty Or, contract law could impose on you an obligation to tell me what you know about the condition of the car Forcing you to share information is efficient, since it makes us more likely to trade The second purpose of contract law is to encourage the efficient disclosure of information within the contractual relationship.
22
21 Breach
23
22 A contract is just a promise The idea here is that we want some promises to be legally binding This means there has to be some legal consequence for breaking such a promise Breach of contract is when the promisor fails to live up to his promise Just like property rights are meaningless unless there is a remedy when they are violated… …contract law is meaningless unless there is a penalty for breach So, what happens when a contract is breached? So…
24
23 Why does the penalty for breach matter? If penalty is too weak, contract law has no bite, and we’re back to our original problem But sometimes, circumstances change, and breach of contract becomes desirable Example: I promise to sell you a painting
25
24 Why does the penalty for breach matter? If penalty is too weak, contract law has no bite, and we’re back to our original problem But sometimes, circumstances change, and breach of contract becomes desirable Example: I promise to sell you a painting Example: I promise to build you a plane If penalty for breach is too severe, I’ll have to honor these promises even when this is inefficient Can we design the law so that we only get breach of contract when it’s efficient?
26
25 When is breach efficient? Breach is efficient if social benefit of breach > social cost of breach Social cost of breach is that promisee doesn’t get the benefit from the promise Social benefit of breach is that promisor doesn’t have to incur the cost of delivering (performing) So breach is efficient if promisor’s cost to perform > promisee’s benefit from performance
27
26 Efficient Breach Promisor’s Cost Promisee’s Benefit Efficient to Breach Promisor’s Cost Promisee’s Benefit Efficient to Perform Efficiency:
28
27 When do we expect breach to happen? Promisor weighs private cost of performance vs breach Whatever the penalty for breach, if it’s cheaper to perform, promisor will perform; if it’s cheaper to breach, he’ll breach That is, we expect breach to occur whenever promisor’s cost to perform > penalty for breach
29
28 Efficient Breach Promisor’s Cost Promisee’s Benefit Efficient to Breach Promisor’s Cost Promisee’s Benefit Efficient to Perform Promisor’s Cost Promisor’s Liability Promisor will Breach Promisor’s Cost Promisor’s Liability Promisor will Perform What will actually happen (incentives of promisor): Efficiency:
30
29 So how do we get efficient breach? Promisor’s Cost Promisee’s Benefit Efficient to Breach Promisor’s Cost Promisor’s Liability Promisor will Breach What will actually happen (incentives of promisor): Efficiency: Promisor’s Liability for Breach Promisee’s Benefit from Performance So if we design the law such that the promisor will breach exactly when breach is efficient
31
30 Efficient breach When liability from breach = promisee’s benefit from performance, we get breach exactly when it’s efficient So for efficiency, when a promisor breaches a contract, we want him to owe a penalty exactly equal to the benefit the promisee expected to receive This is called expectation damages Expectation damages: if I promise you something that has value of $100 to you, and then I break my promise, I owe you $100 This way, if it costs me more than $100 to keep my promise, I’ll break it, which is efficient if it costs me less than $100 to keep my promise, I’ll keep it, which is efficient
32
31 I build airplanes You value one of my planes at $500,000 You agree to buy one for $350,000, and pay up front After you pay, price of materials goes up Example of efficient breach Value to you = $500,000 Price = $350,000
33
32 Promisee’s benefit = $500,000 If it costs me less than $500,000 to build plane, efficient to build it If it costs me more than $500,000, efficient to breach Example of efficient breach Value to you = $500,000 Price = $350,000 Promisor’s Cost Promisee’s Benefit Efficient to Breach
34
33 Liability is just to return your money If my costs rise to $400,000, performance is still efficient, but I’ll choose to breach Liability is $1,000,000 If costs rise to $700,000, performance is inefficient, but I’d rather perform than breach Liability = promisee’s benefit ($500,000) I’ll perform when performance is efficient, breach when breach is efficient Example of efficient breach Value to you = $500,000 Price = $350,000 Promisor’s Cost Promisor’s Liability Promisor will Breach
35
34 Liability is $350,000, my costs rise to $400,000 I’ll breach original contract, but we can renegotiate to higher price But I might try to do that even if my costs don’t go up… Liability is $1,000,000, my costs rise to $700,000 Rather than performing, I can offer you money to let me cancel contract But my threat point is very low – you can demand a lot of money If I realize that might happen, maybe I’m afraid to sign original contract Expectation damages avoid these problems But so what? Can’t we just “Coase” back to efficiency? Value to you = $500,000 Price = $350,000
36
35 If I breach contract, I impose externality on you You’re $500,000 worse off If I have to pay you $500,000, then I internalize the externality Now my action no longer affects your well-being (You get a payoff of $500,000 if I build the plane, and a benefit of $500,000 if I don’t.) So I choose efficiently when deciding whether to perform or breach Another way to think about expectation damages: eliminating an externality
37
36 Reliance (plan to end here)
38
37 Reliance Reliance – investments made by promisee, to increase the value of performance The fourth purpose of contract law is to secure optimal reliance
39
38 When is reliance efficient? When social benefit of reliance > social cost of reliance Social benefit is increased benefit to promisee when promise is performed Social cost is cost borne by promisee, whether or not promise is performed So reliance is efficient as long as (probability of performance) X (increase in value) > (cost)
40
39 Efficient reliance Efficiency: reliance is efficient as long as (probability of performance) X (increase in value) > (cost) We said expectation damages = expected benefit from performance Should expectation damages include increase in benefit due to reliance? If yes: promisee will rely as long as (increase in value) > (cost) So if yes, promisee will overrely (Another way to think about this: there’s some chance I’ll have to breach If your reliance increases my liability, then it increases the expected damages I’ll owe, which makes me worse off If your reliance imposes a negative externality, you’ll do it more than the efficient amount)
41
40 Reliance increases your benefit from my promise Airplane gives you benefit of $500,000 Costs $75,000 to build a hangar Airplane with hangar gives you benefit of $600,000 Suppose price is $350,000, to be paid on delivery Expectation damages restore you to well-being you expected to have from performance Without a hangar, if I breach, I owe you $150,000 If you build a hangar and I breach, do I owe you $250,000? Reliance and Damages: example
42
41 Cost of building plane: maybe $250,000, maybe $700,000 Clearly, you’ll choose to build the hangar But, is that efficient? Reliance and damages: example Price of plane = $350,000 Value of plane = $500,000 Cost of hangar = $75,000 Value of plane + hangar = $600,000 -150150-250 - 75 + 250 = 175 Costs rise 350 - 250 = 100 500 - 350 = 150 350 - 250 = 100 600 - 75 - 350 = 175 Costs stay low I getYou getI getYou get You don’tYou build hangar
43
42 Let p be probability my costs go up Combined expected payoffs if you rely: (1 – p) (175 + 100) + p (175 – 250) = 275 (1 – p) – 75 p = 275 – 350 p Combined expected payoffs if you don’t rely: (1 – p) (150 + 100) + p (150 – 150) = 250 (1 – p) = 250 – 250 p Which is bigger? 275 – 350 p > 250 – 250 p 25 > 100 p p < ¼ So if p ¼, it’s not But you’re going to rely either way! Reliance and damages: example Price of plane = $350,000 Value of plane = $500,000 Cost of hangar = $75,000 Value of plane + hangar = $600,000
44
43 When probability of breach is low, more reliance tends to be efficient When probability of breach is high, less reliance tends to be efficient If expectation damages include increased benefit from reliance, we sometimes get overreliance (OTOH, if expectation damages exclude increased benefit from reliance, liability < benefit, so inefficient breach) What do we learn?
45
44 Cooter and Ulen: include only efficient reliance Perfect expectation damages: restore promisee to level of well- being he would have gotten from performance if he had relied the efficient amount So promisee rewarded for efficient reliance, not for overreliance So what do we do?
46
45 Cooter and Ulen: include only efficient reliance Perfect expectation damages: restore promisee to level of well- being he would have gotten from performance if he had relied the efficient amount So promisee rewarded for efficient reliance, not for overreliance Actual courts: include only foreseeable reliance That is, if promisor could reasonably expect promisee to rely that much So what do we do?
47
46 1850s England Hadley owned gristmill, mill shaft broke Baxendale’s firm hired to transport shaft for repair Baxendale shipped by boat instead of train, making it a week late Hadley sued for the week’s lost profits “The shipper assumed that Hadley, like most millers, kept a spare shaft. …Hadley did not inform him of the special urgency in getting the shaft repaired.” Court listed several circumstances where broken shaft would not force mill to shut down Ruled lost profits not foreseeable Baxendale didn’t have to pay Foreseeable reliance: Hadley v Baxendale
48
47 Default rules What principles should we use to address contingencies not considered in a contract? Paper by Ayres and Gertner on syllabus Up next
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.