Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published byElmer Price Modified over 9 years ago
1
Dynamic Pricing with Risk Analysis and Target Revenues Baichun Xiao Long Island University
2
Outline Risk-neutral- a basic assumption of most RM models; its inability to deal with short-term behavior; Literature review; What affects short-term risk? A RM model with a target revenue and penalty function; Concluding remarks.
3
Risk Neutral Assumption of RM Models Decision makers are risk neutral; i.e., all models attempt to maximize the expected revenues at the end of the disposal period; Optimal in the long run (the law of large numbers): no single realization has the potential for severe revenue impacts on the company; Not necessarily the best option in the short run.
4
Risk-Neutral May Not Apply to Short- Term Compelling reasons for concerning short- term revenues: Financial constraints; Uncompromised revenue goals or minimum probability of achieving these goals; Shareholders’ requirements; All of the above are escalated by the perishability of products.
5
Risk with Short-term Revenues Short-term revenues can swing drastically from their long-term estimates because: Uncertainty of demand; Forecast errors; Speculations; Unexpected capacity changes. A single poor performance can be very damaging and may not be compromised by the long-term average.
6
Example One
7
Practitioners’ Solutions Sacrifice expected revenues in return for higher probability of achieving a revenue goal. Liquidations; Clearances; Negotiated discounts; Favorable price for large-volume demand.
8
Example Two
9
Theoretical Framework? Current RM models are unable to explain why a dynamic control policy leads to a steep dive of prices during liquidation periods; unable to explain discount policies for large- volume demand.
10
Related Research McGill and van Ryzin (1999): addressed importance and challenge of pricing group demand. Bitran and Caldentey (2002): “essentially all the models that we have discussed assume that the seller is risk neutral.” Feng and Xiao (1999): a risk-sensitive pricing model to maximize sales revenue of perishable products.
11
Related Research Kleywegt and Papastavrou (1997), Slyke and Young (2000), Brumell and Walczak (2003): pricing group demand, but not from the perspective of risk. Lim and Shanthikumar (2004): (i) a model built upon erroneous forecast parameters may perform badly and present a risk; (ii) robust dynamic pricing; (iii) equivalent to single product dynamic RM with exponential utility function without parameter uncertainty;
12
Related Research Levin, McGill, and Nediak (2005): (i) motivated by inventory clearance of high-value items (automobiles, electronic equipment, appliances, etc.); (ii) permit control of the probability that total revenues fall below a minimum acceptable level; (iii) augment the expected revenue objective with a penalty term for the probability that revenues drop below a desirable level.
13
Related Research Feng and Xiao (2005): (i) Maximize the risk- averse utility function instead of risk-neutral revenue; (ii) The risk-averse utility model retains monotone properties of the optimal policy; (iii) Risk-neutral models are special cases of risk-averse models; (iv) The risk- averse model explains behaviors that cannot be rationalized by the risk-neutral assumption; e.g., group discount policy.
14
How is Risk Measured? Risk is normally measured by variance and standard deviation; Variance and standard deviation are policy dependent; Variance and standard deviation are affected by the remaining inventory and time-to-go; Penalty function using the standard deviation is not a proper choice when the time-to-go is diminishing.
15
Risk is Affected by Policy 2015 35 20 55 295.75306.66 69.321.8
16
Variance vs. Remaining Inventory Variance increases with the remaining Inventory.
17
Variance vs. Remaining Inventory A single-policy model ( ):
18
Variance vs. Remaining Inventory
19
General cases (inventory control)
20
Variance and Time Remaining
21
Coefficient of Variation
22
Risk of Selling Perishable Products For a given policy, risk increases if the remaining inventory increases; For a given policy, risk increases if the time- to-go diminishes; Risk can be controlled by policy.
23
Alternatives for Reducing Risk Expected revenue with a penalty function when the target revenue is not met; Expected revenue with a penalty function when the probability of not achieving the target revenue is above a threshold; Risk-averse expected utility function;
24
Distribution of Revenues
27
A Continuous-Time Pricing Model with Target Revenue Assumptions: Management has a target revenue in the short run; If the target is not met, a penalty is incurred; The penalty is proportional to the deficit of revenue; Management makes price decisions to maximize the expected revenue with a penalty of not meeting the target.
28
Notations
29
Objective Function optimal expected revenue at T given the remaining inventory and realized revenue at t be n(t) and r(t), respectively; The revenue function has three parameters t, n, and r.
30
Boundary Conditions when t = T Note: (i) Penalty is incurred if r < r 0 ; (ii) The penalty function is piecewise linear.
31
Boundary Conditions when t = T Implication: sell remaining inventory in the neighborhood of T for any price.
32
Boundary Conditions when n = 0 Note: V(t, 0, r) is independent of t.
33
Boundary Conditions when n = 0 For r 1 > r 2,
34
Optimality Condition Only one price is accepted at any given time; Optimal price is chosen from the price set P ( may not be the highest price).
35
Optimality Condition If p i is the optimal solution at t with realized revenue r, then
36
Optimality Condition Result: If then the optimal price in the neighborhood of T is the lowest price ; The lowest price has the highest revenue rate.
37
Solve V(t, 1, r) In the neighborhood of T, leads to
38
Solve V(t, 1, r)
39
Let In the left neighborhood of, the optimal price becomes Other thresholds are similarly defined.
40
Solve V(t, n, r) Assume has been obtained; In the neighborhood of T, is the optimal price, V(t, n, r) is given by
41
Solve V(t, n, r) Let In the left neighborhood of, the optimal price becomes Other thresholds are similarly defined.
42
Numerical Experiment Data:
43
Expected revenue with the target r 0 r0r0 V(0, M, 0) 500738.93 550738.88 600738.24 650734.16 700718.27 750678.39 800609.03 850516.27 900416.81
44
Expected Revenue with the Target r 0 Expected Revenue 400 450 500 550 600 650 700 750 800 4005006007008009001000 r0 V(0,M,0) V(t,n,r) is a decreasing function of r 0.
45
Expected revenue as Function of c cV(0, M, 0) 1.0728.53 1.2726.47 1.4724.41 1.6722.36 1.8720.31 2.0718.27 2.2716.23 2.4714.19 2.6712.15 Note: r 0 =700
46
Expected revenue as Function of c V(t,n,r) is a decreasing and linear function of c.
47
Expected revenue as Function of n V(t,n,r) is increasing and concave in n for fixed t and r. (r 0 =700)
48
Expected Revenue as Function of r V(t, n, r) is an increasing function of r for fixed t and n (r 0 =700).
49
Expected Revenue as Function of t V(t,n,r) is a decreasing and concave function of t for given n and r; but V(t,n,r)-V(t,n-1,r) may not decrease in t (r 0 =700).
50
Property of V(t,n,r+s) -V(t,n,r)
51
Concluding Remarks Decision makers are risk-averse in financial market and many other areas, revenue management should not be an exception; The proposed pricing model handles risk with a target revenue and a penalty function; Many properties of risk-neutral models seem to hold except the marginal expected revenue;
52
Concluding Remarks More structural properties of the value function need to be uncovered; Whether pricing policy for group demand can be dealt with by the proposed model need to be explored.
Similar presentations
© 2024 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.