Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

TWO VIEWS OF THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN GOVERNMENT AND MARKETS 1.Markets are inherently unstable, and government policy is stabilizing. 2. Markets are inherently.

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "TWO VIEWS OF THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN GOVERNMENT AND MARKETS 1.Markets are inherently unstable, and government policy is stabilizing. 2. Markets are inherently."— Presentation transcript:

1

2 TWO VIEWS OF THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN GOVERNMENT AND MARKETS 1.Markets are inherently unstable, and government policy is stabilizing. 2. Markets are inherently stable, and government policy is destabilizing.

3 A FUNDAMENTAL DIFFERENCE BETWEEN MICROECONOMICS AND MACROECONOMICS Microeconomics focuses on a particular market (say, the market for oranges). It puts the rest of the economy “on hold” by invoking the ceteris paribus assumption. Showing how a particular market works is based on the assumption that all other markets are working fine. Macroeconomics focuses on large sectors of the economy (say, on input markets, such as the market for labor, or on output markets). It deals with the interaction among the different sectors and shows that, under certain assumptions, disturbances or malfunctions in one sector can infect all other sectors.

4 PART I: From Supply and Demand to Circular Flow

5 PART I From Supply and Demand to Circular Flow Supply and demand curves keep track of prices and quantities. Multiply the p times the q for output markets to get expenditures (e). Sum the expenditures in output markets to get total expenditures (E) Multiply the w times the n for input markets to get income (y). Sum the incomes in all input markets to get total income (Y) Macroeconomic equilibrium requires that Y = E.

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

13 “Market clearing” in the microeconomic sense is consistent with—and allows for—the natural rate of unemployment.

14

15

16

17

18

19

20

21

22

23

24

25

26 The equality here of Y and E does not deny the possibility of saving—which can get spent, too, by someone else.

27 E = Y = 3000 is just for illustration. For actual data, check the Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED).FRED

28 PART II: The Macroeconomics of Depression

29 PART II: The Macroeconomics of Depression Suppose the economy suffers a weakening of demand for output. Prices do not adjust--at least not immediately. Output adjusts, as do expenditures: PQ becomes PQ’ With E less than Y, excess inventories accumulate. The demand for labor (and other resources) falls. Wages do not adjust--at least not immediately. The level of employment adjusts: WN becomes WN’ Y is brought into line with E through adjustments in N.

30

31

32

33

34

35

36 MID-SHOW QUIZ: According to microeconomists, equilibrium (in the market for a particular good) is a balance between quantity supplied and quantity demanded and is achieved by the appropriate change in the good’s price.

37 MID-SHOW QUIZ: According to microeconomists, equilibrium (in the market for a particular good) is a balance between quantity supplied and quantity demanded and is achieved by the appropriate change in the good’s price.

38 MID-SHOW QUIZ: According to microeconomists, equilibrium (in the market for a particular good) is a balance between quantity supplied and quantity demanded and is achieved by the appropriate change in the good’s price.

39 MID-SHOW QUIZ: According to macroeconomists, equilibrium (for the economy as a whole) is a balance between income and expenditures and is achieved by a change in the level of employment.

40 MID-SHOW QUIZ: According to macroeconomists, equilibrium (for the economy as a whole) is a balance between income and expenditures and is achieved by a change in the level of employment.

41 MID-SHOW QUIZ: According to macroeconomists, equilibrium (for the economy as a whole) is a balance between income and expenditures and is achieved by a change in the level of employment.

42 PART III: The Macroeconomics of Inflation

43 PART III The Macroeconomics of Inflation Suppose the economy experiences a strengthening of demand for output. Output cannot rise (except temporarily) above the full-employment level. Prices begin to rise The demand for labor increases Wages begin to rise. The supply of labor shifts as workers demand cost of living adjustments. The supply of output shifts to reflect the increased labor costs. Y and E are finally brought into balance through adjustments in P and W.

44

45

46

47

48

49

50

51 PART IV: The L-Shaped Supply Curve

52 PART IV The L-Shaped Supply Curve Suppose the economy is in deep depression. Imagine that the demands for output (and hence for input) are rising. From deep depression to full employment, Q and N rise. From full employment onward, P and W rise. The path traced out by P and Q (and by W and N) forms a backwards L. Query: can the economy now move backwards along the backwards L? Does the “path traced out” constitute a genuine supply curve?

53

54

55

56

57

58

59 PART V: From P and Q to Y and E

60 PART V From P and Q to Y and E Microeocnomics tracks prices and quantities because both p and q (and both w and n) change in response to changing market conditions. If p and w always adjusted quickly and painlessly, there would be no depressions--no lapses from full employment. Because we do actually experience depressions (or recessions), we can infer that prices and wages do not always adjust quickly and painlessly. The simplest way to derive the implications of slow and painful adjustments is to assume that p and w do not change at all. With p and w fixed, then changes in Q and N imply proportionate changes in expenditures (E = PQ) and in income (Y = WN). (For market conditions that are pushing the economy beyond its full-employment level, we take Q and N to be fixed (except for temporary, or unsustainable, upward movements). In this case changes in E and Y imply proportionate changes in P and W.)

61

62

63

64

65

66

67

68

69

70

71

72

73

74

75

76

77

78

79

80

81 = PQ = WN P(Q ) W(N ) (P )Q (W )N

82 PART VI: The Components of Income and Expenditures

83 INCOME AND EXPENDITURES Wages (salaries) earned by labor Rents earned by land owners Interest earned by capitalists Profits earned by entrepreneurs

84 INCOME AND EXPENDITURES Consumption Investment Government

85 INCOME AND EXPENDITURES Consumption Investment Government Wages Rents Interest Profits Y C + I + G =

86 Income-Expenditure analysis, as introduced by John Maynard Keynes in 1936, hinges not on how people earn their incomes but rather on how they spend them. If all the income gets spent, then the economy is in “equilibrium,” but it is not necessarily performing at its full- employment potential. YC + I + G=

87 WHY DIVIDE EXPENDITURES INTO THREE COMPONENTS? Consumption Investment Government C + I + G Stable Unstable Stabilizing Stabilizable Not constant but predictable on the basis of income. Affected by unpredictable shifts in investment demand. Deliberately altered with an eye to shifting investment demand. Potentially stable—with wise and well-time stimulant packages.

88 = PQ = WN On its own, the economy will deliver itself to some point on this orange line. But it is adjustments in employment that brings income and expenditures in line with one another. The goal of government policy is to nudge the economy towards the blue point---the one point on the orange line at which the economy is functioning at full employment without inflation.

89


Download ppt "TWO VIEWS OF THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN GOVERNMENT AND MARKETS 1.Markets are inherently unstable, and government policy is stabilizing. 2. Markets are inherently."

Similar presentations


Ads by Google