Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Gruppo CNR di economia internazionale Torino, 22-23 Febbraio 2007 “The decline in Italian productivity: new econometric evidence” by S. Fachin & A. Gavosto.

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "Gruppo CNR di economia internazionale Torino, 22-23 Febbraio 2007 “The decline in Italian productivity: new econometric evidence” by S. Fachin & A. Gavosto."— Presentation transcript:

1 Gruppo CNR di economia internazionale Torino, 22-23 Febbraio 2007 “The decline in Italian productivity: new econometric evidence” by S. Fachin & A. Gavosto Discussion by Carlo Altomonte (Università Bocconi)

2 The main contributions of the paper The paper address the source of the productivity slowdown in Italy through panel cointegration methods Three relevant contributions: 1.The use of panel cointegration methods allows to relax the assumption of CRS and perfect competition in factor markets, typical of the growth accounting approach 2.The use of a flexible form for the production function (Kmenta linearisation of the CES) allows to discuss the relevance of the labour/capital elasticity of substitution 3.The results are comparable with other, more traditional studies, as in their Figure 6, and thus more prone to a generalisation

3

4 1. Panel cointegration methods - I The authors start from the labour productivity equation They assume that technical progress p it can be decomposed as: p it =  t +  i and thus they can write: where the industry-specific technological progress is incorporated in  ’ But if the shock is not entirely separable (i.e. not every industry follows the same growth rate of technological progress over time), then the term becomes: p it =  t +  i +  it and thus  it in (3) should incorporate the term  it, leading to an error term potentially correlated with the input choices (simultaneity bias).

5 1. Panel cointegration methods - II They implicitly discuss this issue by estimating Here they assume that the term φ in (4) captures not only the trend in the technical progress but also the effect of any other random shock. As a result, they have to impose an assumption on the distribution of these shocks: they are (log) additive and generated by a symmetric distribution, so that  s = E(φ s | t=s) and φ can be estimated non-parametrically However, again they implicitly assume that the shocks are entirely separable across industries, which in the panel structure is not likely  openly discuss the issue of simultaneity bias  elaborate more on the actual restrictiveness of the assumptions on , and the potential correlation of shocks across time/industries (e.g. by discussing the characteristics of the VCov Matrix of their panel estimation)

6 2. Capital-labour elasticity of substitution Their equation for log labour productivity (2) does not impose a unitary K/L elasticity of substitution  as in Cobb-Douglas And yet, they cannot reject but for one industry (Rubber) the null of , although the confidence intervals of the point estimates are rather large This result mimics Balistreri, McDaniel and Wang (2003) for the US economy (1947-1998, 28 industries), but the authors are still skeptical on  Large confidence intervals are really caused by different underlying elasticity of substitution, or by the model design ? One implication of aggregate equations like (2) is that, with , any redistribution of inputs across plants (i.e. any linear combination of  ’x) results in the same aggregate output, which is not true: if firms are heterogeneous in productivity levels and new inputs flow to the most productive firms, different linear combinations would yield different results => “noise” in the estimates Here the assumption on the elasticity of substitution is relaxed, but a potential bias from the aggregation problem persists => large confidence intervals could be due to the aggregation bias, while  holds.

7 If  (i.e. a Cobb-Douglas specification) cannot be excluded, what do we learn from the Kmenta specification ? Would the results dramatically change using a Cobb-Douglas ? And a translog ? The broad dynamics of TFP recovered through the panel cointegration are similar to standard growth accounting analyses, but the order of magnitude is rather different: more than double of the growth rate in the period 1986-90 and almost a third in 1991-95: Is this due to the fact that TFP estimates in this paper are valid only for the long-run ? If this is the case, how big is the error incurred in trying to use these estimates in order to explain the business cycle ? If TFP estimates are ok also for the short run, how to explain the much higher volatility of the business cycle implied by these TFP figures ? 3. Relevance of the results


Download ppt "Gruppo CNR di economia internazionale Torino, 22-23 Febbraio 2007 “The decline in Italian productivity: new econometric evidence” by S. Fachin & A. Gavosto."

Similar presentations


Ads by Google