Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published byHoratio McCarthy Modified over 9 years ago
1
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2012 Lecture 20
2
1 Discussion question – recapping tort law ChoiceBad LuckOutcome + punish the choice criminal law regulations punish the combination of choice and outcome negligence rule punish the outcome strict liability rule QUESTION: What are the pros and cons of each approach?
3
2 Thinking about the legal process
4
3 Developed theories of property/nuisance law, contract law, and tort law Looked at how rules of legal liability create incentives Thought about how these rules can be chosen to try to achieve efficient outcomes Over the last three months, we have…
5
4 To achieve efficiency, we’ve generally tried to set a party’s liability equal to the harm he caused someone else Damages in nuisance law Expectation damages in contract law Compensatory damages in tort law That way, he internalizes the externality he imposes, leading to efficient decisions In doing this, we’ve been making two big assumptions: The legal system works flawlessly The legal system costs nothing Over the last three months, we have…
6
5 I hit you with my car and did $10,000 worth of damage We both know I was negligent But courts aren’t perfect If we go to trial, 80% chance I’ll be found liable, 20% I won’t If I’m held liable, damages are correctly set at $10,000 So on average, if we go to trial, you expect to recover $8,000 But if we go to trial, we both have to hire lawyers Suppose this costs us each $3,000 Now your expected gain from going to trial is $8,000 – 3,000 = 5,000 And my expected cost is $8,000 + 3,000 = 11,000 An example from Polinsky, “An Introduction to Law and Economics”
7
6 So… Going to trial gains you $5,000 (in expectation) Going to trial costs me $11,000 (in expectation) Maybe we can settle out of court If we avoid going to court and I pay you any settlement between $5,000 and $11,000, we’re both better off So maybe this happens But… An example from Polinsky, “An Introduction to Law and Economics”
8
7 Suppose I’m more pessimistic about my chances than you You think I’m 80% likely to be found liable I think I’m 90% likely to be found liable You think your expected gain is $8,000 – 3,000 = $5,000 I think my expected cost is $9,000 + 3,000 = $12,000 Now the range of possible settlements is even wider Any settlement between $5,000 and $12,000 is a Pareto- improvement over going to trial So settling is more likely An example from Polinsky, “An Introduction to Law and Economics”
9
8 Now instead, suppose I’m more optimistic about my chances than you You think I’m 80% likely to be found liable I think I’m only 10% likely to be found liable You think your expected gain is $8,000 – 3,000 = $5,000 I think my expected cost is $1,000 + 3,000 = $4,000 Now an out-of-court settlement is impossible There are no settlements that you and I would both agree to An example from Polinsky, “An Introduction to Law and Economics”
10
9 And, even if our beliefs are compatible and there are settlements that we would both prefer to trial… …private information might lead to failure to reach a settlement Remember from before: if our threat points are private information, we might fail to reach an agreement because each of us is holding out for too big a share So even if we had the same beliefs about what will happen at trial, private information could prevent settlement An example from Polinsky, “An Introduction to Law and Economics”
11
10 So when litigation is costly… If the two parties agree on the likely outcome of a trial, there are gains from settling out of court, and a range of settlements they would both prefer to going to trial If the two parties are relatively pessimistic, settlement is even more likely If the two parties are relatively optimistic, settlement may be impossible Even if the two have the same beliefs or are relatively pessimistic, private information may lead to failures in bargaining An example from Polinsky, “An Introduction to Law and Economics”
12
11 Under strict liability… We said injurers internalize cost of accidents efficient precaution But this assumes cost of being sued = damage done If courts are unpredictable and litigation is costly, private cost of being sued for damages could be > or < cost of accident Which could lead to too much or too little precaution But also… If settlement talks break down and cases go to trial… …then total social cost of an accident includes the harm done, and the resources expended during the trial! If trial costs $6,000, then social cost of the accident isn’t $10,000, but $16,000 – which increases the efficient level of precaution! So what?
13
12 Tort law: efficiency meant minimizing the total social cost of accidents Actual cost of accidents Plus cost of actions taken to prevent them (precaution) Goal of the legal process: minimize its social costs Direct (administrative) costs Error costs What is the goal of the legal process?
14
13 Administrative costs Hiring judges, building courthouse, paying jurors… More complex process higher cost Error costs Any legal process is imperfect Errors are any judgments that differ from theoretically perfect ones An error in computing damages after the fact only affects distribution, not efficiency But anticipated errors affect incentives, which may lead to actions which aren’t efficient Error costs are costs of distortions in actions people take (precaution, activity levels, etc.) due to flaws in legal system Administrative costs and error costs
15
14 So theoretically, the efficient legal process is the one that minimizes the sum of… The direct costs of administering the system, and The economic effects of errors due to that process not being perfect The goal of the legal process
16
15 The legal process
17
16 Once an accident has happened… Victim could sue or not sue The victim and injurer might quickly settle out of court If the case proceeds to trial, the first step (in the U.S.) is a pre-trial exchange of information After that, victim and injurer might still settle out of court If the case goes to trial, victim (now plaintiff) might win or lose Losing side at trial can choose to appeal (or not) The legal process
18
17 Stages of the legal process… decision to pursue a legal claim bargaining over out-of-court settlements pre-trial exchange of information trial itself appeals process
19
18 In a rational world, victim compares cost of filing a lawsuit to expected gain from suing How to calculate expected value of a legal claim? Why sue?
20
19 Why sue? Sue? Settle immediately or exchange info? Settle then or go to trial? Win or lose at trial? Appeal? Don’t FileFile Settle“Discovery” SettleTrial WinLose NoYes Win or Lose Appeal? WinLose Harm done: $100 70% chance you settle immediately Average settlement is $50, legal costs of $1 Discovery process costs $3.30 70% chance you settle after discovery, average settlement is $50, legal costs of $1 Trial costs $20 Plaintiff wins with probability 50%, damages = harm Appeal costs $20 Appeal succeeds with probability 10%, damages = harm
21
20 Why sue? Sue? Settle immediately or exchange info? Settle then or go to trial? Win or lose at trial? Appeal? Don’t FileFile Settle“Discovery” SettleTrial WinLose NoYes Win or Lose Appeal? WinLose $100 – $20 = $80–$20 10%90% –$10$0 50% $100 – $20 = $80–$20 $30 Harm done: $100 70% chance you settle immediately Average settlement is $50, legal costs of $1 Discovery process costs $3.30 70% chance you settle after discovery, average settlement is $50, legal costs of $1 Trial costs $20 Plaintiff wins with probability 50%, damages = harm Appeal costs $20 Appeal succeeds with probability 10%, damages = harm
22
21 Why sue? Sue? Settle immediately or exchange info? Settle then or go to trial? Win or lose at trial? Appeal? Don’t FileFile Settle“Discovery” SettleTrial WinLose NoYes Win or Lose Appeal? WinLose $100 – $20 = $80–$20 10%90% –$10$0 50% $100 – $20 = $80–$20 $30$50 – $1 = $49 70%30% 70% * $49 + 30% * $30 = $43.30 Harm done: $100 70% chance you settle immediately Average settlement is $50, legal costs of $1 Discovery process costs $3.30 70% chance you settle after discovery, average settlement is $50, legal costs of $1 Trial costs $20 Plaintiff wins with probability 50%, damages = harm Appeal costs $20 Appeal succeeds with probability 10%, damages = harm
23
22 Why sue? Sue? Settle immediately or exchange info? Settle then or go to trial? Win or lose at trial? Appeal? Don’t FileFile Settle“Discovery” SettleTrial WinLose NoYes Win or Lose Appeal? WinLose $43.30 – $3.30 70%30% $50 – $1$43.30 70% * $49 + 30% * $40 = $46.30 Harm done: $100 70% chance you settle immediately Average settlement is $50, legal costs of $1 Discovery process costs $3.30 70% chance you settle after discovery, average settlement is $50, legal costs of $1 Trial costs $20 Plaintiff wins with probability 50%, damages = harm Appeal costs $20 Appeal succeeds with probability 10%, damages = harm
24
23 Why sue? Sue? Don’t FileFile $46.30$46.30 – filing costs$0 Harm done: $100 70% chance you settle immediately Average settlement is $50, legal costs of $1 Discovery process costs $3.30 70% chance you settle after discovery, average settlement is $50, legal costs of $1 Trial costs $20 Plaintiff wins with probability 50%, damages = harm Appeal costs $20 Appeal succeeds with probability 10%, damages = harm
25
24 Why sue? Sue? Don’t FileFile $46.30 – filing costs$0 Decision to sue If expected value of legal claim > filing costs, we expect victim to file a claim If expected value of legal claim < filing costs, we expect victim not to
26
25 So there are three things that directly influence the number of lawsuits The number of injuries The cost of filing a complaint The expected value of a claim Holding everything else constant… More injuries should mean more claims Holding fixed the number of accidents, lower filing costs, or higher expected value of claims, mean more claims But things can sometimes get more complicated… Number of lawsuits
27
26 Number of lawsuits Typical level of damages not worth suing for most victims more precaution fewer accidents
28
27 Expected value of claims should vary widely Filing costs Probability Expected value of claims Filing Fee SUE DON’T SUE
29
28 Recall the efficient legal system minimizes the sum of administrative costs and error costs Higher filing fees fewer lawsuits lower administrative costs But, higher filing fees more injuries go “unpunished” greater distortion in incentives higher error costs Filing fee is set optimally when these balance on the margin: Marginal cost of reducing fee = marginal benefit Administrative cost of an additional lawsuit = error cost of providing no remedy in the marginal case Filing costs
30
29 Error costs If we’re only concerned with efficiency, we don’t care about distributional effects That is, we don’t care if a particular victim is or isn’t compensated So the size of error costs depends on how much peoples’ behavior responds to the incentives caused by liability “The social value of reducing errors depends on whether the errors affect production or merely distribution” When errors have large incentive effects, filing fees should be low When errors have small incentive effects, efficiency requires higher filing fees Filing costs
31
30 As long as there are any filing fees or other costs to litigation, some harms will be too low to justify a lawsuit When harm is small to each individual but large overall, one solution is a class action lawsuit Filing costs Probability Expected value of claims Filing Fee SUE DON’T SUE
32
31 One or more plaintiffs bring lawsuit on behalf of a large group of people harmed in a similar way Example: California lawsuit over $6 bounced-check fee Court must “certify” (approve) the class Participating in a class-action suit eliminates victim’s right to sue on his own later If suit succeeds, court must then approve plaintiff’s proposal for dividing up the award among members of the class Class-action suits are desirable when individual harms are small but aggregate harms are large… Especially when avoidance of liability has strong incentive effect But there’s also a danger Class Action Lawsuits
33
32 Agency problem Client wants lawyer to work on case until marginal cost of more work equals marginal benefit This is hard to achieve through a contract, because lawyers face their own incentives One solution: 100% commission (client “sells lawsuit to lawyer”) But this is illegal Common solution: reputation Lawyers and clients
34
33 Stages of the legal process… decision to pursue a legal claim bargaining over out-of-court settlements pre-trial exchange of information trial itself appeals process
35
34 Trials are costly to both parties If both parties agree on expected outcome of a trial, both are better off agreeing to out-of-court settlement on similar terms If two sides are relatively optimistic about their chances in court, this may be impossible After lawsuit filed but before trial, parties have opportunity to negotiate a settlement, and to exchange information relevant to trial Some information exchange is mandatory “Discovery” process in U.S. – each side must supply opponent with evidence they plan to use, answer questions about case In Europe, no pre-trial discovery; instead, first stage of trial involves similar sharing of information in front of judge Does voluntary pooling of information promote settlement? Does involuntary pooling of information promote settlement? Exchange of Information
36
35 Parties tend to disclose information that corrects the other side’s relative optimism I hit you with my car I think your injuries were minor, damages might be $1,500 You know they were serious, have x-rays and doctor’s reports to prove it, know damages will be $15,000 Going to trial costs us each $3,000 As things stand: I expect trial to cost me $4,500; you expect to gain $12,000; settlement seems unlikely But you’re happy to show me your evidence Once I see it, I might offer a bigger settlement, we both avoid cost of trial Parties tend to withhold information that would correct other side’s relative pessimism Either way, voluntary exchange of information tends to encourage settlement Voluntary exchange of information
37
36 Cooter and Ulen: Trials occur when the parties are relatively optimistic about their outcome, so that each side prefers a trial rather than settlement on terms acceptable to the other side. When the parties are relatively optimistic, at least one of them is uninformed. Pooling of information before trial that reduces relative optimism promotes settlement. Furthermore, by revealing private information to correct the other side’s false optimism, the party making the disclosure increases the probability of settling on more favorable terms. Voluntary exchange of information
38
37 Involuntary disclosure will tend to reveal information the parties would otherwise choose to withhold This is usually information that corrects relative pessimism So forced disclosure may make settlement less likely On the other hand, involuntary disclosure reduces uncertainty, makes two sides’ threat points more clear May make reaching a settlement easier So overall effect is unclear Involuntary disclosure may also delay settlement until after disclosure occurs What about involuntary exchange of information?
39
38 Disclosure (“discovery”) rule in the U.S. very extensive Parties reveal basic arguments they’ll make, evidence that supports them, names of witnesses, nature of each witness’s testimony Each side can inspect other’s evidence, question its witnesses Witnesses or evidence not disclosed during discovery may not be allowed at trial Most European countries have little or no pre-trial discovery Europe: juries rarely used in civil cases Delays and interruptions less costly, more common Under civil law, judges take more active role in developing arguments and exploring evidence What about involuntary exchange of information?
40
39 Voluntary disclosure encourages settlements Fewer trials, simpler/quicker trials lower administrative costs Settlement terms get closer to likely trial outcome; if this judgment would likely be correct, this reduces error costs Involuntary disclosure Might lead to more or fewer trials Should lead to simpler, shorter trials Discovery is also a costly process Overall effect on administrative costs could be positive or negative Pools much of the information that would come out at trial, so settlements should deviate less from trial outcomes So involuntary disclosure should reduce error costs Effect of information disclosure on administrative and error costs
41
40 Stages of the legal process… decision to pursue a legal claim bargaining over out-of-court settlements pre-trial exchange of information trial itself appeals process
42
41 Plaintiff might accept settlements S when S > Expected Judgment Plaintiff – Legal Costs Plaintiff Defendant might offer settlements S when S < Expected Judgment Defendant + Legal Costs Defendant So settlement is possible when EJ P – LC P < EJ D + LC D which is when EJ P – EJ D < LC P + LC D Pre-Trial Bargaining degree of relative optimism combined legal costs
43
42 Suppose parties agree on expected judgment EJ If bargaining fails and case goes to trial, Plaintiff gets expected payoff EJ – LC plaintiff Defendant gets expected payoff – EJ – LC defendant So these are threat points during bargaining Combined payoffs are – LC plaintiff – LC defendant If settlement is reached, combined payoffs are 0 So gains from cooperation are LC plaintiff + LC defendant If gains from cooperation are split evenly… Plaintiff’s payoff is (threat point) + ½ (gains) = (EJ – LC plaintiff ) + ½ (LC plaintiff + LC defendant ) = EJ – ½ LC plaintiff + ½ LC defendant Pre-Trial Bargaining
44
43 We just concluded… If the two parties agree on expected outcome of trial… …and successfully negotiate a settlement… …and divide gains from cooperation equally… then settlement = EJ – ½ LC P + ½ LC D If going to trial is equally costly to both parties, this is just EJ – the expected judgment at trial But if trial is more costly to defendant, this would be more Pre-Trial Bargaining
45
44 A nuisance suit is a lawsuit with no legal merit If it goes to trial, defendant will definitely win (EJ = 0) Sole purpose of a nuisance suit is to force a settlement Just found: “reasonable settlement” = EJ – ½ LC P + ½ LC D So if LC P = LC D, nuisance suit is pointless – reasonable settlement would be 0 But suppose going to trial is very costly for defendant Publicity would be bad for defendant’s reputation Or, developer has to settle lawsuit to avoid delaying construction LC P is just legal fees But LC D includes legal fees plus other costs So even if lawsuit has no merit, defendant might feel forced to pay a settlement Nuisance Suits
46
45 Example Cost of going to trial is $5,000 for defendant, $1,000 for plaintiff Expected judgment = 0 Threat points are -5,000 and -1,000 Gains from cooperation are 6,000 If gains are split evenly, plaintiff’s payoff is (threat point) + ½ (gains) = -1,000 + ½ (6,000) = 2,000 So nuisance suit might lead to a settlement of $2,000, even though expected judgment at trial is 0 Nuisance Suits
47
46 Even without relative optimism, settlement negotiations may fail due to private information Ex: defendant made a faulty product, which injured lots of people Some sustained minor injuries, say $2,000 Some sustained major injuries, say $10,000 Before trial, defendant can’t tell scope of plaintiff’s injuries Suppose legal costs are $500 for each side If ½ of plaintiffs had major injuries, average injury = $6,000 So reasonably settlement offer might be $6,000 But if all defendants are offered a settlement of $6,000, the ones with minor injuries will take it, and the ones with major injuries will go to trial Defendant has two choices: Offer settlements large enough that everyone will accept But then even people with very minor injuries, or none, might sue Or offer only small settlements, and get stuck going to trial in many cases Failures in negotiations
48
47 Stages of the legal process… decision to pursue a legal claim bargaining over out-of-court settlements pre-trial exchange of information trial itself appeals process
49
48 In Europe… Judges in civil trials take active role in asking questions and developing case “Inquisitorial system,” since judge asks questions In U.S… Lawyers’ job to develop case Judge is more of a passive referee “Adversarial system,” since competing lawyers are adversaries Trial
50
49 Lawyers have a strong incentive to win at trial May be working on contingency Value reputation for winning Judges have no stake in outcome of the trial Judges will (we hope) generally do what is right… …but have less motivation to work hard “Judges have incentives to do what is right and easy; lawyers have incentives to do what is profitable and hard.” Incentives
51
50 In U.K., loser in a lawsuit often pays legal expenses of winner Discourages “nuisance suits” But also discourages suits where there was actual harm that may be hard to prove In U.S., each side generally pays own legal costs But some states have rules that change this under certain circumstances Who pays the costs of a trial?
52
51 Rule 68 of Federal Rules of Civil Procedure “At any time more than 10 days before the trial begins, a party defending against a claim may serve upon the adverse party an offer [for a settlement]… If the judgment finally obtained by the offeree is not more favorable than the offer, the offeree must pay the costs incurred after the making of the offer.” “Fee shifting rule” Example I hit you with my car, you sue Before trial, I offer to settle for $6,000, you refuse If you win at trial, but judgment is less than $6,000… …then under Rule 68, you would have to pay me for all my legal expenses after I made the offer Who pays the costs of a trial?
53
52 Rule 68 does two things to encourage settlements: Gives me added incentive to make a serious settlement offer Gives you added incentive to accept my offer But not actually as generous as it sounds Attorney’s fees not always included in fees that are covered Asymmetric Plaintiff is penalized for rejecting defendant’s offer Defendant is not penalized for rejecting offer from plaintiff Who pays the costs of a trial?
54
53 Kathryn Spier, “Pretrial Bargaining and the Design of Fee- Shifting Rules” Game-theory analysis of Rule 68 and similar rules Shows that when parties have private information, fee-shifting rules like this increase probability of settlement Then considers designing “perfect” rule to maximize number of cases that would settle out of court Ideal rule is similar to two-sided version of Rule 68 Take each side’s most generous settlement offer Compute a cutoff If eventual judgment is below this cutoff, plaintiff pays both sides’ legal fees; if above cutoff, defendant pays both sides’ fees Who pays the costs of a trial?
55
54 Trial has to answer two questions: Is defendant liable? If so, how much are damages? Unitary trial considers liability and damages at same time Economies of scope Segmented trial considers liability first, then damages later (if necessary) Damages phase may not be necessary In U.S., judges have discretion over which type of trial Unitary versus Segmented Trials
56
55 Burden of proof: who is responsible for showing what at trial In criminal case, prosecutor’s burden to show defendant is guilty, not defendant’s burden to show he’s innocent Similarly, in civil case, plaintiff’s burden to make case Under negligence rule, plaintiff has to prove defendant was negligent (rather than defendant having to show he was not) Under contributory negligence, once defendant is shown to be negligent, it’s defendant’s burden to show plaintiff was also negligent Burden of proof
57
56 Standard of proof: degree of certainty to which something must be shown in court In criminal cases, “beyond a reasonable doubt” – very high standard In civil cases, plaintiff usually has to prove case by “a preponderance of the evidence” Much lower standard – interpreted as anything over 50% certainty For punitive damages to be awarded, high standard of proof is often required: “clear and convincing evidence” Efficient level depends on relative costs of two types of errors Finding someone liable when they should not be Finding someone not liable when they should be Standard of proof
58
57 Rules for what evidence court can pay attention to Textbook gives examples where rules seem inconsistent, if goal is simply to maximize probability of “right outcome” When we focus on efficiency, we care only about outcomes, not about process But in real-world legal system, process is important in its own right Rules of evidence
59
58 Stages of the legal process… decision to pursue a legal claim bargaining over out-of-court settlements pre-trial exchange of information trial itself appeals process
60
59 In U.S., three levels of federal courts District courts, circuit courts of appeals, Supreme Court (Many state court systems also have three levels, but this varies by state) Parties in district court cases have right of appeal Circuit court is required to consider their appeal Parties in circuit court cases do not Supreme Court has discretionary review – chooses which cases to hear In common law countries, appeals courts tend to only consider certain issues Appeals generally limited to matters of law Matters of fact generally not considered Appeals
61
60 Recall goal of legal system Minimize administrative costs + error costs Clearly, appeals process increases administrative costs So only efficient if it reduces error costs Reasons why appeals process may reduce error costs Appeals courts are more likely to reverse “wrong” decisions than “right” decisions… …which leads to losing parties appealing more often when decision was “wrong” Appeals
62
61 Stages of the legal process… decision to pursue a legal claim bargaining over out-of-court settlements pre-trial exchange of information trial itself appeals process
63
62 Up next: criminal law If you want to read ahead: Friedman chapter 15, or Becker paper Up next
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.